Evaluating the free market by comparing it to the alternatives (We don't need more regulations, We don't need more price controls, No Socialism in the courtroom, Hey, White House, leave us all alone)
"Politicians have recently called on the Federal Reserve to address
issues of racial and income inequality. Current and former Fed officials
have pointed out that monetary policy is too broad a tool to accomplish
this narrow goal. Yet the Fed may have the ability to affect inequality
by other, more effective means.
Presidential candidate Joe Biden has recommended
that “the Fed should aggressively enhance its surveillance and
targeting of persistent racial gaps in jobs, wages, and wealth.” A
similar proposal
by Senator Elizabeth Warren would require the Fed to pursue “the
elimination of disparities across racial and ethnic groups with respect
to employment, income, wealth, and access to affordable credit.”
Improving the livelihoods of minorities and low-income earners is a
noble goal. Economists widely agree, however, that these objectives
cannot be achieved using monetary policy.
Inequality is a long-term, structural issue that cannot be resolved
with monetary policy, as former Fed Chairs Ben Bernanke and Janet Yellen
have acknowledged. “The degree of inequality we see today,” Bernanke said,
“is primarily the result of deep structural changes in our economy that
have taken place over many years.” Because “monetary policy is a blunt
tool,” Bernanke argued that “policies designed to affect the
distribution of wealth and income are, appropriately, the province of
elected officials, not the Fed.”
In 2016 Congressional testimony, Yellen similarly emphasized the
broad nature of monetary policy. “A stronger labor market,” she said,
“will improve the status of all groups in the labor market.” But
addressing inequality is more difficult since “there are deeper
structural reasons that these trends continue.”
Current Fed Chair Jerome Powell also recently expressed skepticism
regarding the Fed’s ability to deal with income inequality. Noting the
broad nature of monetary policy, he said that “a tight labor market is
probably the best thing that the Fed can foster to go after that
problem.” Powell emphasized that Congress, rather than the Fed, may be
more equipped to deal with issues of inequality. “We don’t really have
tools that can address distributional disparate outcomes as well as
fiscal policy.”
The Fed does, however, have another means by which it can combat
inequality. It could eliminate excess regulations that inhibit bank
competition and the hiring of low-skilled workers.
Standard economics teaches that regulations tend to reduce
competition and economic efficiency. Until the 1990s, US banks were
generally prohibited from opening branches in other states and sometimes
even within their home state. These restrictions made the banking
industry less efficient, resulting in higher costs for bank customers. Restrictions on branch banking also make it difficult to diversify investments, which makes the banking system less stable.
From the 1970s through the 1990s, many states eliminated branch
banking restrictions, allowing greater competition in the banking
industry. Studies of this period find that eliminating these state-level
regulations lowered loan rates for borrowers, improved entrepreneurship, and reduced economic volatility.
In a 2010 study,
Thorsten Beck, Ross Levine, and Alexey Levkov consider whether
deregulations during this period affected income inequality. They look
at several measures of inequality such as the Gini coefficient, Theil
index, and the ratio of the 90th to 10th percentiles of income. The evidence shows that “branch deregulation substantially reduced income inequality.”
The authors are careful to account for other effects that might bias
their results. They control for local economic conditions, such as
state-level unemployment rates and GDP growth, demographic differences,
such as the percentages of blacks and female-headed households, and
other policies, such as labor market reforms. The results consistently
show that bank deregulation reduced inequality.
Beck, Levine, and Levkov also test whether reductions in inequality
are driven by changes at the low or high ends of the income
distribution. Their results, reproduced in the figure below, find that
deregulation was associated with gains to the lower levels of the income
distribution without significant effects on higher levels of the
distribution.
They further examine the timing of effects on workers at the lowest
income levels. As seen in the figure below, the relative real wages of
unskilled workers increased considerably in the years following
deregulation. Bank deregulation also appears to have boosted employment
opportunities as illustrated by lower rates of unemployment and higher
working hours for unskilled workers.
Bank deregulation since the 1970s has had important economic effects
of reducing income inequality and improving economic stability. The
evidence suggests that, unlike monetary policy, deregulation is one
avenue by which the Fed might have meaningful effects on reducing income
inequality.
To be clear: I am not recommending bank regulators relax their
emphasis on bank safety and soundness. Regulators must always remain
focused on financial stability, but trimming excess regulations would
reduce barriers to entry for new banks and ease the regulatory burdens
of smaller banks that pose no risk to the banking system. A study by Richard Herring, for instance, found that bank capital regulations “could be reduced by 75% with no loss of rigor.”
In fact, reducing the number of regulations can often be more
effective at constraining bank risk. In the same way that a complex tax
code creates loopholes to avoid the law, a complex regulatory system
enables banks to avoid compliance. Strong but simple regulations can improve financial stability without creating undue costs of regulatory compliance.
Nor am I suggesting that racial disparities be made a primary focus
of regulation. Efforts by the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau
(CFPB) to target discriminatory lending practices, for example, have
made lending to minorities more costly and less common.
A more prudent approach is to eliminate unnecessary barriers to
competition. Such a change is likely to increase opportunities for those
with lower incomes and narrow the wage gap between low-skilled and
high-skilled workers.
Economic theory suggests, and evidence confirms, that the burden of
regulations is likely to fall on the least well-off members of society.
Limiting regulation encourages competition in the banking system,
resulting in lower costs for consumers and more hiring of low-skilled
workers.
If the Fed aims to reduce inequality, it should use policies that are
known to be effective. There is little scope for affecting inequality
with monetary policy. Reducing banks’ regulatory burden reduces
inequality by improving the lives of Americans with the lowest incomes."
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.