skip to main |
skip to sidebar
A Carbon Tax Is Not A Slam Dunk
By David R. Henderson. Excerpt:
"economists who advocate Pigovian taxes take as given that the
most-efficient way to forestall global warming is to reduce the amount
of carbon used. But what if their assumption is incorrect?
There are at least three important reasons to conclude that the
assumption is wrong. First, cow farts. That’s right: cow farts. A far
more potent greenhouse gas than carbon dioxide is methane. Methane,
which is present in cow farts, warms the planet much more quickly than
carbon dioxide before decaying to carbon dioxide. The UN’s
Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), which is generally
thought of as the scorekeeper on global warming, estimates that over the
approximate decade before it decays, methane warms the earth by a
whopping 86 times as much as CO2. To be sure, the CO2
lasts much, much longer than methane, but the fact of methane’s huge
short-run potency surely suggests that a tax on carbon may not be the
cheapest way to forestall global warming.
Second, one important technological development over the last decade
has been “geo-engineering.” The idea here is to change other things in
the atmosphere that are easier to change than the amount of carbon used.
Consider what we learned from the June 1991 eruption of Mount Pinatubo,
in the Philippines. That eruption poured 20 million tons of sulfur
dioxide into the stratosphere. Over the next two years, the effect of
that one eruption was to reduce the earth’s temperature by about 1
degree Fahrenheit. That might not sound like much but it’s actually over
half the 1.4 degree warming that has happened over the last century.
What if every year we could put sulfur dioxide in the atmosphere so as
to permanently prevent the earth from warming? In their 2009 book Superfreakonomics,
University of Chicago economist Steven D. Levitt and writer Stephen J.
Dubner point out that if we could get just 34 gallons per minute of
sulfur dioxide into the stratosphere (which translates to about 100,000
tons per year), that would reverse warming in the high Arctic and reduce
it in much of the Northern Hemisphere. Why focus on such high latitude
areas? Because, note Levitt and Dubner, “high-latitude areas are four
times more sensitive to climate change than the equator.” How would you
get the SO2 into the atmosphere. Levitt and Dubner cite the
thinking of Nathan Myhrvold, at one time the chief technology officer
for Microsoft. Mrhrvold argues that if we had a big enough hose, we
could do it.
Is such a technology feasible right now? Maybe not. But if it were,
it would be incredibly cheap. Myhrvold’s organization, Intellectual
Ventures, estimated that it could be set up in two years for $20 million
and an annual operating cost of about $10 million.
Those are not large numbers, especially compared to the cost of a
carbon tax. In December 2018, the Congressional Budget Office estimated
that a carbon tax of $25 per metric ton for the 10-year period from 2019
to 2028 would generate cumulative revenue for the U.S. government of
$1.1 trillion. The cost of building and operating the SO2 hose would be a rounding error on that number.
But isn’t geo-engineering risky? Couldn’t it have negative unintended
consequences? Yes and yes. But everything we do is risky, including
imposing more taxes on carbon. Moreover, taxing carbon is an indirect
form of geo-engineering.
The third low-cost way to rein in global warming is by planting trees. Trees absorb and store CO2
emissions. You could call the tree-planting strategy geo-engineering,
but it would count as such in a very low-tech form. According to a July
4, 2019 article in The Guardian,
planting one trillion trees would be much cheaper than a carbon tax and
much more effective. At an estimated cost of 30 cents per additional
tree, the overall cost would be $300 billion. That’s large, but it’s a
one-time cost. Moreover, writes The Guardian’s environment
editor Damian Carrington, such a tree-planting program “could remove
two-thirds of all the emissions that have been pumped into the
atmosphere by human activities, a figure the scientists describe as
‘mind-blowing’.” A carbon tax, by contrast, would simply slow the rate
of emissions into the atmosphere.
It’s true that there would still be the problem of how to pay for
that extra trillion trees. Thirty cents per tree is small but one
trillion is large. Yet my point is the one I started out with: there are
potentially much cheaper ways to deal with global warming than a carbon
tax.
Advocates of such a tax might argue that it could be set up to give
money to people per tree planted. It could, but notice that the key is
not that it’s a carbon tax but that it’s a per-tree subsidy. The carbon
tax would still be much more expensive, for a given amount of global
warming prevented, than such a subsidy.
Perhaps you find too uncertain the idea that geo-engineering, either
high-tech or of the arboreal variety, is at the stage where it would
slow or reverse global warming. That may be. But here’s what we know.
First, imposing a tax on carbon is very expensive. Second, taxing carbon
gives little incentive to find other solutions that are less expensive.
Wouldn’t the incentive to find other solutions be high because doing so
would help major energy companies argue against a carbon tax. They
would certainly have the incentive to argue, but the incentive to
discover lower-cost solutions would be small. To the extent a major
energy company found such solutions, and to the extent it persuaded
governments to back off the carbon tax, it would be helping its
competitors and billions of consumers, not just itself. These other
companies and consumers would be free riders on that one company’s
effort.
It’s possible that somewhere down the road, we will conclude that,
for reasons we don’t yet know that make geo-engineering infeasible, a
carbon tax is a good idea. But we’re not close to that conclusion yet. A
carbon tax is not a slam dunk."
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.