skip to main |
skip to sidebar
The Solution to Congestion
By Randal O'Toole of Cato.
"It is distressing, at least to economists, how many problems could be
solved by adopting basic free-market principles, yet those solutions
are ignored or stridently opposed by the very people who would benefit
from them. California’s drought is one of those: California actually has plenty of water, it is just poorly priced.
An even more pervasive problem is traffic congestion, which (according to the Texas Transportation Institute)
wasted more than 3 billion gallons of fuel and nearly 7 billion hours
of people’s time for a total cost of $160 billion in 2014. Brookings
economist Anthony Downs wrote a whole book about congestion that concluded there was no solution
to the problem–except, he noted almost parenthetically, congestion
pricing which Downs decided was politically impossible. Of course,
that’s a self-fulfilling prophecy because if no one argues for something
because it’s impossible, it will truly be impossible.
Fortunately, more people are beginning to argue for congestion pricing. A November 27 report from an economic group in Canada called the Ecofiscal Commission argues that “pricing traffic congestion is critical to beating it.”
An even more recent report,
released on December 8 by the Royal Academy of Engineering, makes a
similar argument for roads in Britain. The report compares a wide
variety of programs, including transit improvements, smart roads, and
urban redevelopment, and concludes that road pricing offers the greatest
value for the money and has no net cost to taxpayers.
One reason congestion pricing doesn’t happen is that many people see
it as an attempt to force people off the roads and out of their cars. So
it is disappointing that neither of these reports notes the critical
finding of my Cato policy analysis on congestion pricing, which is that road pricing actually increases the capacity of roads to move people and vehicles during busy times of the day.
As the paper shows, a freeway lane can move up to 2,000 vehicles per
hour at 55 miles per hour, but when traffic slows because of congestion,
throughput can fall below 1,000 vehicles per hour. By preventing such
traffic slowdowns, road pricing can paradoxically double road capacities
during rush hour, thus giving everyone more options to get where they
want to go without delay, not less.
Another obstacle to congestion pricing is that people don’t trust
government. Optimally, highway managers would set prices just high
enough to keep traffic flowing and use net revenues to pay for more
congestion relief, not boondoggles elsewhere. Some of the most efficiently constructed tollways in the world follow these principles.
Unfortunately, other systems have not followed these principles, giving tollroads everywhere a black eye. One of the worst is the Dulles Toll Road,
which was built by the state of Virginia in 1984 and worked well for
many years. Then the state gave it to the Metropolitan Washington
Airport Authority, which more than quadrupled tolls so it could use the
surplus to subsidize the Silver Line boondoggle.
Yet one bad toll road is not an argument against congestion pricing, any more than the failure of A&P
is an argument against all supermarkets. Congestion pricing is the best
and may be the only way to end the fuel, time, and dollars wasted in
traffic, and free-market advocates should support such pricing to solve
local traffic problems."
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.