skip to main |
skip to sidebar
Faster approval times should lead to drug innovation and saved lives
See
The FDA and Magical Thinking by by Alex Tabarrok.
"Vox had a piece yesterday on the Cruz-Lee proposal to
make it easier for U.S. patients to access drugs and devices already
approved in other developed countries. The Vox piece had some howlers.
Most notably this:
“There’s no evidence the FDA blocks innovation or makes innovation harder or makes it more costly,” said Kesselheim.
Frankly, that would be laughable were it not coming from a professor of medicine at Harvard Medical School. It costs well over a billion dollars
to get the average new drug approved and much of that cost comes from
FDA required clinical trials. Longer and larger clinical trials mean
that the drugs that are eventually approved are safer. But longer trials
also mean that good drugs are delayed. And the more expensive it is to
produce new drugs the fewer new drugs will be produced. In short, longer
and larger trials mean drug delay and drug loss.
We live in a world of tradeoffs. Let’s debate the tradeoffs. But
let’s not engage in magical thinking where there are no tradeoffs and
“no evidence” that the FDA makes drug development more costly.
A more subtle error was committed by the author who writes:
But it’s not clear that this legislation can solve the
biggest problem here — the lack of promising treatments in the pipeline.
In other words, a faster approval process can’t fix a dearth of
innovation from labs themselves.
Many factors go into drug development that are outside the FDA’s
purview. Nevertheless, faster drug approval can and does increase
innovation. Approving drugs more quickly is equivalent to a decrease in
the costs of research and development. Time is money. Reducing the cost
of development increases the incentive to develop new drugs.
The Prescription Drug User Fee Act, for example, reduced drug approval times by about 10 months. Philipson et al. calculate that:
…the more rapid access of drugs on the market enabled by PDUFA saved the equivalent of 140,000 to 310,000 life years.
(PDUFA does not appear to have materially affected safety but Philipson et al. calculate that even under a worst case scenario the benefits of PDUFDA far exceeded the costs).
Moreover, Vernon et al. find that the reduction in approval time from PDUFA increased new drug development:
Controlling for other factors such as pharmaceutical
profitability and cash flows, we estimate that a 10% decrease (increase)
in FDA approval times leads to an increase (decrease) in R&D
spending from between 1.4% and 2.0%. Combining this estimate with recent
research on the link between PDUFA and FDA approval times…we calculate
PDUFA may have incentivized an additional $10.8 billion to $15.4 billion
in pharmaceutical R&D. Recent economic research has shown that the
social rate of return on pharmaceutical R&D is very high; therefore,
the social benefits of PDUFA (over and above the benefits of more rapid consumer access) are likely to be substantial.
Finally, return to the issue of reciprocity. Many of the critics of
reciprocity respond with simple appeals to nationalism. We are the best!
Rah, rah, rah! But if the critics were German or French they would
argue that the EMA is superior to the FDA. Indeed, when I raise the
issue of reciprocity with Europeans they respond in exactly the same way
as Americans. How could anyone suggest that the EMA automatically
approve drugs approved by the FDA! The horror.
The argument for reciprocity, however, isn’t that the FDA is uniquely
bad or always worse than the EMA or vice-versa. The argument is that
it’s wasteful to duplicate the lengthy approval process and that both
agencies sometimes make mistakes. As a result, it’s simple common sense
to let Americans avail themselves of drugs and devices approved in
other developed countries."
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.