Evaluating the free market by comparing it to the alternatives (We don't need more regulations, We don't need more price controls, No Socialism in the courtroom, Hey, White House, leave us all alone)
Friday, February 23, 2024
The Economics and Implications of Compliance with Minimum Wages
"Recent research suggests that wages below legally established minimum
wages are surprisingly prevalent. This column reviews ‘wage theft’ in
the US and its impact on the wage gains workers might otherwise enjoy.
Most firms comply with increases in the minimum wage, especially when
they have time to plan for the increase, but evasion and avoidance are
also qualitatively important features of the low-wage labour market.
Young African American workers experience the largest erosion of their
potential wage gains following a minimum wage increase. Whether greater
enforcement would improve the welfare of low-wage workers, however,
remains an open question.
Minimum wages remain of great interest to economists because their
employment effects are contested and because they shed light on
important issues in the labour market, like the degree to which it is
competitive. They are also a perennial policy issue. The most recent
example is the decision of many countries and US states to substantially
increase their wage floors in response to the tight labour markets and
rapid nominal wage inflation of the past two years.
As with any regulation, it is important for both economists and
policymakers to understand compliance to holistically evaluate minimum
wages. Recent research suggests that wages below legally established
minimum wages are surprisingly prevalent (Bhorat et al. 2017,
Goraus‐Tańska and Lewandowski 2019, Rani et al. 2013). Much of this
research further finds that when wage floors are higher than average
wages, estimated employer compliance rates tend to be lower.
Declines in compliance in the wake of minimum wage increases raise
several questions of relevance to policymakers. First, how prevalent is
noncompliance and how much does it reduce the magnitude of the wage
gains workers might otherwise enjoy? Second, are the costs of
noncompliance borne disproportionately by workers from disadvantaged
groups? Third, to what extent is noncompliance a response by firms to
mitigate the need for more drastic changes like reductions in
employment?
The prevalence of sub-minimum wage payment following minimum wage increases
In our paper (Clemens and Strain 2022), we attempt to better
understand minimum wage compliance by studying compliance on the margin.
Specifically, we estimate the increase in sub-minimum wage payment –
i.e. ‘wage theft’ – following changes in the minimum wage.
Among relatively younger hourly wage workers (ages 16 to 25) in the
US, we estimate that a one dollar increase in the minimum wage is
associated with a 29 cent increase in wages and a 3.6 cent increase in
sub-minimum wage payment. Across a number of analyses and population
sub-samples, increases in sub-minimum wage payment following minimum
wage increases range between 10% and 20% of the magnitude of realised
wage gains.
This evidence leads us to conclude that most firms comply with
increases in the minimum wage, but that evasion and avoidance are also
qualitatively important features of the low-wage labour market.
The extent to which employers have time to plan for a minimum wage
increase appears to have an effect on compliance. We find that minimum
wage increases from new legislation are associated with substantially
larger increases in sub-minimum wage payment than minimum wage increases
that come about due to automatic inflation indexing, which has been
adopted by a number of US states. The latter increases are regular and
forecastable, giving firms more time to adapt. This may increase
compliance, with firms adjusting to the increase in labour costs along
other margins, potentially including employment (Brummund and Strain
2020). Similarly, we find that, for relatively small minimum wage
increases, noncompliance rises for 2 to 3 years and subsequently
declines. This suggests that firms may turn to noncompliance as a part
of their short-run response but over time adopt alternative strategies
to absorb or otherwise adapt to the rise in wages.
Which groups are most impacted by sub-minimum wage payment following minimum wage increases?
Which workers are affected the most by sub-minimum wage payment? In a
second paper (Clemens and Strain 2023), we study whether sub-minimum
wage payment varies across demographic groups. By and large, we find
that the bite of underpayment is similar for workers of different ages
and of different racial and ethnic groups. Put differently, in the wake
of minimum wage increases, increases in underpayment tend to amount, as
mentioned above, to between 10% and 20% of the realised wage gains.
That said, we do find some notable differences among different
demographic groups. Among young workers (ages 16 to 21), we find that a
one dollar increase in the minimum wage increases the wages of
(non-Hispanic) African American workers by 28 cents and increases
underpayment by 9.4 cents – the magnitude of the underpayment is 33.2%
of the magnitude of the wage increases. In contrast, among the full
sample of young workers, underpayment amounts to 13.8% of realised wage
gains. Relatively young African American workers thus emerge in our
analysis (Figure 1) as the primary group for which this ratio is
unusually large: increases in underpayment erode an unusually large
fraction of the wage gains these workers might otherwise have
experienced.
Among a broader sample (those aged 16 to 65), variations in the share
of wage gains that are eroded by underpayment are modest, as also shown
in the figure. Of note in this broader sample is that Hispanic workers
are disproportionately impacted by both the wage increases and increases
in underpayment that occur in the wake of minimum wage increases, such
that the ratio is ultimately similar to what we see for the full sample.
Figure 1 Increase in underpayment as a per cent of realised wage gains per dollar of minimum wage increase by demographic group
Implications for assessing minimum wage policy
The academic and policy debate understandably emphasises the
employment effects of minimum wage increases (e.g. Clemens and Strain
2021). But firms are likely to respond to minimum wage increases across a
variety of margins, including the generosity of the benefit packages
they offer to workers, the amount of exertion they require of workers on
the job, and perhaps even schedule irregularity (Clemens 2021, Dworsky
et al. 2022, Meiselbach and Abraham 2023, Ku 2022, Coviello et al. 2022,
Clemens and Strain 2020). Noncompliance is an additional method to
which firms might turn when adjusting to increases in mandated labour
costs.
This leaves open the question as to whether greater enforcement
measures would improve the welfare of low-wage workers broadly, and of
members of disadvantaged groups, who may be disproportionately impacted
by wage theft.
On the one hand, more aggressive enforcement would likely reduce the
magnitude of sub-minimum wage payment relative to realised wage gains.
On the other hand, to the extent that firms resort to noncompliance to
avoid more severe adjustments like reducing their employee headcount,
ramped-up enforcement measures may reduce job opportunities among
low-wage workers. The effect of the former would be to increase
earnings; the effect of the latter would be to decrease them. This
trade-off has been considered in recent work (Garnero and Lucifora
2022). Additional analyses of interest have highlighted connections
between minimum wages and compliance with tax law (Gavoille and Zasova
2023a,b).
Analyses of optimal minimum wages can approach the issue from a
number of perspectives (Ahlfeldt et al. 2022, Dustman et al. 2021).
Apart from the welfare effects of more aggressive enforcement, an
additional welfare consideration is broader, pitting the rule of law
against economic efficiency. The rule of law requires that regulations
be followed and that low-wage workers be paid at minimum the wages they
are legally owed. That said, some of the wage theft in the low-wage
labour market may be economically efficient if it enables voluntary and
mutually beneficial transactions between workers and firms. In this
sense, noncompliance with minimum wage regulation may blunt the
regulation’s distortionary employment effects.
We highlight this trade-off not as a rationalisation for
noncompliance, but instead to argue that policymakers (and economists)
should better appreciate the tension between economic efficiency and the
rule of law that arises with minimum wage regulation. Any holistic
assessment should include this consideration."
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.