Evaluating the free market by comparing it to the alternatives (We don't need more regulations, We don't need more price controls, No Socialism in the courtroom, Hey, White House, leave us all alone)
"Tonight I would like to focus on the arguments made by those who
believe the amount of government debt doesn’t matter. For years,
economists have been debating the best way to reduce the debt to GDP
ratio. The fear is that we may soon cross over to a point of no return
which inevitably leads to some form of debt crisis. However, in recent
years, a growing number of economists and commentators have come to
believe that the debt doesn’t matter. If we just ignore the 70s, then,
thanks to permanent low interest rates and low inflationary risks, we
will be able to disregard the debt and achieve low unemployment and high
output.
There are problems with this position. First, the fact that interest
rates have stayed low in recent years does not mean that they will never
significantly rise. It might take a while, but the prospects are strong
that they’ll eventually go up. Second, and maybe more importantly, even
if interest rates never increase and inflation never materializes,
there is a significant cost to high debt which is best avoided,
especially if one values smaller government. Debt is only the symptom of
overspending, i.e. an expansion of the size of government with all the
distortions that comes with such a growth.
Debt, Inflation and Interest Rates
Now this is by far my least favorite part of my talk because I will
be the first to acknowledge that monetary policy isn’t my area of
expertise. Keeping this in mind, here are some of my thoughts on this
issue.
One of the most common arguments for why debt doesn’t matter is the
fact that the inflation-worriers have been with us for decades, yet
inflation has only trended downward. It is true that US inflation has
been stuck at low levels for 25 years now, for reasons no one seems to fully understand.
More recently, despite the Fed flooding the economy with money, and the
latest $8 trillion in spending paid for with borrowing, selected data
suggest that the risk of high inflation is low. Some scholars,
for instance, point out that inflation rates remain below 2 percent,
and when measured properly, the forecast for the average inflation rate
over the next five years is under 1.5 percent, well below the Fed’s
target for action, thanks, they believe, to investors’ supposedly
incurable appetite for US debt.
This argument may be correct for the time being, or even for the next five years. It is worth noting that some argue, including one of my co-panelists, that inflation is already here.
While I don’t have the expertise to weigh on this issue, I do believe
that we are in the process of what economist Arnold Kling describes as a guy of jumping out of a 10-story window, and as he passes the 2nd floor informs the bystanders that “See, so far so good!”
The Hoover Institution economist John Cochrane makes
a similar argument when he writes that “Yes, I’ve warned about it
before, and no, it hasn’t happened yet. Well, if you live in California
you live on an earthquake fault. That the big one hasn’t happened yet
doesn’t mean it never will.”
For one thing, while it is true that the Cleveland Fed shows that
inflation rates are below 2 percent, others do not share that view. For
instance, the New York Fed predicts that the inflation rate will be 3.1%
a year out, while the Philadelphia Fed predicts a rate of 2.5%. The
prediction of the Atlanta Fed is 2.4%. Which one is right? I wonder
whether it is possible that we are seeing inflation but not taking these
signs into account. Could the surge in the prices of real estate prices
or of Bitcoin—or of equities—be the sign of a vote no confidence?
There is no doubt that US treasuries remain popular with foreign
investors. But does it mean that interest rates on debt will be low
forever? I am not sure about that. Over at Discourse Magazine, my colleague Jack Salmon argues
that since 2013 (when foreign holdings of US debt as share of GDP
peaked), debt-to-GDP has risen from 71% to 101%. Over the same 8 year
period, debt held by foreign investors as a share of GDP has actually
fallen from 35% to 33%. The growth in debt significantly outpaces
foreign demand for US treasuries. What’s more, over this same period of
time, total US debt held by foreign investors has fallen from around
half to less than a third.
The point is that bond market investors willingness in the past to
lend 100% of GDP to the US government at 1% interest says very little
about their willingness to do the same when our debt to GDP stands at
200 percent (which we are set to reach in 2050 without accounting for
the Biden administration new spending or assuming no future wars,
recessions or emergencies). There is a limit out there somewhere, a
tipping point that even the most prominent debt doves out there admit
exists. Cochrane writes:
There is a limit, a debt/GDP
beyond which markets will not lend. On this, I think, we all agree.
There is a finite fiscal capacity. Even though in theory the r<g
argument would allow a 1,000% debt to GDP ratio, or 10,000%, at some
point the party stops. The closer we are to that limit, the closer we
are to a real crisis when we need that fiscal capacity and it is no
longer there.
Another important point is that we shouldn’t take much comfort from
the fact that rates are low today and that they are projected to be low
in the next few years because all of that could change very quickly with
no advance notice. Cochrane writes:
No, interest rates do not signal such problems. (Alan Blinder, covering such matters in the Wall Street Journal,
”if the U.S. Treasury starts to supply more bonds than the world’s
investors demand, the markets will warn us with higher interest rates
and a sagging dollar. No such yellow lights are flashing.) They never
do. Greek interest rates were low right up until they weren’t. Interest
rates did not signal the inflation of the 1970s, or the disinflation of
the 1980s. Lehman borrowed at low rates until it didn’t. Nobody expects a
debt crisis, or it would have already happened.
In other words, these events are very hard to predict with data. This leads me to my final point. In a recent essay for Law & Liberty, Kling reminds us of the work of IMF economists Carmen Reinhart and M. Belen Sbrancia, which shows that:
Throughout history, debt/GDP
ratios have been reduced by (i) economic growth; (ii) substantive fiscal
adjustment/austerity plans; (iii) explicit default or restructuring of
private and/or public debt; (iv) a surprise burst in inflation; and (v) a
steady dosage of financial repression accompanied by an equally steady
dosage of inflation.
Like Kling, I believe that growing ourselves out this mess,
implementing the kind of austerity measures required to reduce our debt
to GDP ratio, or the likelihood of a hard default are unlikely. That
said, my co-panelists, and our moderator Alex Pollock in particular,
have convinced me that financial repression is much easier to implement
and more likely than I assumed. That said, the real interest aspect of
the Reinhart-Sbrancia findings is “a surprise burst in inflation.”
Kling notes, and I agree, that this is the least unlikely scenario. But
Surprise is here the key word. No one saw it coming in the
past, and no one will see it coming when our time finally comes. That is
because, as Kling writes,
In my view, all attempts to
predict inflation using mechanical rules fail. They fail because
inflation depends on the habits, norms, and expectations of the public
at large. If people are habituated to low inflation, then attempts by
the Fed to nudge up the inflation rate will not work…. Conversely, if
people believe that inflation will be high and variable, then they try
their best to protect against this.
If that’s the case, it is essential that people believe that the
Federal Reserve and Congress will be able to rein inflation back in if
it got out of hands. Will they? In a recent article for National Review,
Cochrane reminds us that the means available to the Fed or Congress to
combat fast rising inflation are not pleasant. He also questions whether
people at the time will actually believe that these institutions will
have the will to do what it takes, no matter what the political price
is.
Even if it is true that worries about rising interest rates or rising
inflation are overblown, debt still matters because it carries very
high costs.
Why Debt Matters
Here are a few reasons why high debt matters even if there is no inflation and rates remain low.
Milton Friedman was
correct: The true measure of government’s size is found in what it
spends and not in what it takes in in taxes. Because borrowing allows
politicians and citizen-taxpayers to push the bill for today’s spending
onto future generations, borrowing encourages too much spending
today—thus irresponsibly enlarging the size of government.
First, debt is very expensive. The more we borrow, the higher the
cost of borrowing even if interest rates stay low. In other words, a
very low interest rate on a gigantic debt is still a lot of interest
payments. In 2020, the US government paid $378 billion in interests on
the debt. In GDP terms, assuming no new wars, or major recessions, or
expensive new federal initiatives, the Congressional Budget Office estimates
8.3% of GDP will go to paying interest payments in 2050. With nominal
GDP projected to be $64 trillion by 2050, that in constitutes over $5
trillion in interest payments. That’s much larger than the entire 2019
Federal budget.
CBO also notes
that under very modest projections of interest rate increases, interest
payments will grow from 8 percent of our budget in 2020 to 27 percent
in 2051, or over 40 percent of revenue. At that point, interest payments
will be by far the largest government expenditure. As the CBO office
notes, “even though rising interest rates have a sizable effect on the
fiscal outlook, rising debt levels would substantially boost interest
costs even if rates remained unchanged.” Large growth in interest
payments as a share of the budget will inevitably come at the expenses
of other budget items that people value.
Second, it is also likely that even without inflation, our debt
expansion will lead to an increase in interest rates, which in turn
creates the crisis. Here is how Cochrane explains it:
Let’s grow the debt / GDP ratio to
200%, $40 trillion relative to today’s GDP. If interest rates are 1%,
then debt service is $400 billion. But if investors get worried about
the US commitment to repaying its debt without inflation, they might
charge 5% interest as a risk premium. That’s $2 trillion in debt
service, 2/3 of all federal revenue. Borrowing even more to pay the
interest on the outstanding debt may not work. So, 1% interest is
sustainable, but fear of a crisis produces 5% interest that produces the
crisis.
While demographics and foreign
demand for U.S. debt have put downward pressure on interest rates over
the years, growing debt and deficits have also put upward pressure on
interest rates. Several academic studies have found that each percentage
point increase in the debt-to-GDP ratio raises real interest rates by 2
to 5 basis points, while each percentage point increase in the
deficit-to-GDP ratio raises real interest rates by 18 to 28 basis
points.
Third, overspending that leads to very large annual budget deficits
increases the likelihood that calls for new sources of revenue like a
Value Added Tax will become more politically palatable. In other words,
today’s spending must be financed sooner or later by taxes on someone,
and those taxes will be economically damaging without successfully
reducing our debt levels. The austerity literature
shows that fiscal adjustment packages based mostly on tax increases are
unlikely to succeed while having the deep and negative impact of
economic growth.
Fourth, the money the federal government borrows comes from the
savings of Americans and others who hold dollars. In other words,
government spending and borrowing crowd out private spending and
borrowing.
Fifth, a high debt level slows economic growth down. Assuming we
never face a full on debt crisis like the one we have seen play out in
Greece, then we face the unfortunate, yet increasingly likely
possibility of becoming Japan. There are at least 40 academic studies
published since 2010 observing the debt-growth nexus. The broad
economic consensus revealed in the literature is that while threshold
levels for advanced economies vary from 70 to 100% of GDP, the negative
effect of large and growing public debt levels does indeed have serious
negative effects on economic growth.
Most studies that estimate the economic effects find that for every
10 percentage point increase in the debt ratio, future economic growth
is reduced by 0.2 percentage points. Before the Covid-19 pandemic our
debt-to-GDP ratio was 78%, it is now 101%–this constitutes a loss in
future economic growth of almost half a percentage point. While at 78%
debt we may have grown at 2.5% on average for the years to come, we now
may growth at only 2% thanks to our debt addiction. Compounded over the
years, this fact means that the average American will be significantly
worse over time. With our debt ratio expected to hit 200% in the
long-run, the economic reality of Japanese-style stagnation is something
we should be cognizant of in the debate surrounding our debt
trajectory.
Milton Friedman was correct: The true measure of government’s size is
found in what it spends and not in what it takes in in taxes. Because
borrowing allows politicians and citizen-taxpayers to push the bill for
today’s spending onto future generations, borrowing encourages too much
spending today—thus irresponsibly enlarging the size of government.
For those of us who desire to keep government small, raising debt
levels means a larger and larger increase in the size and scope of
government. It also suggests a lack of accountability as well as a lack
of transparency. For all these reasons we need to reform entitlement
spending, put both large chunks of military and domestic spending on the
chopping block, and start selling off federal assets. Better to do it
now than during a fire sale later."
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.