See
The Slow Vindication of the Austrians by Benjamin J. Thompson at FEE. Excerpt:
"Earlier this month in The New York Times, Neil Irwin noticed with some consternation that low interest rates have a strange way of favoring the biggest players in a market. The revelation came from a chance encounter with on-the-ground experiences of actual entrepreneurs:
Atif Mian, an economist at Princeton, was recently having dinner with
a colleague whose parents owned a small hotel in Spain. The parents had
complained vociferously, Mr. Mian recalled the friend saying, about the
European Central Bank’s[ECB] low interest rate policies.
That didn’t make sense, Mr. Mian thought. After all, low interest
rates should make it easier for small business owners to invest and
expand; that’s one of the reasons central banks use them to combat
economic weakness.
The owners of the small hotel didn’t see it that way. They thought
that big hotel chains were the real beneficiaries of low interest rate
policies, not a mom-and-pop operation.
Empirical Validation
The gee-golly head-scratching about this one strikes me as pretty
funny since the Austrians have argued for the last half-century or more
that artificially low interest rates bias the market in favor of the
Large. Interest rates are the price of access to future money today
subject to the same supply-and-demand pressures as anything else that
has a price. Depending on how much stored capital is sitting in the
banks to lend and how many demands there are to borrow, a natural market
interest rate would emerge. The ECB, just like the Federal Reserve,
takes it upon itself to press a finger on the scale and push that price
down.
Since prices carry information, wrong prices carry wrong information.
In the case of interest rates fixed to be too low, it sends the message
that the economy is ready and waiting for very large capital projects.
Production shifts to larger, more time-intensive projects at the cost of
smaller ones. If this goes on long enough, it becomes the poison boom
that creates a bust later, as it turns out consumers weren’t actually
waiting to buy the ambitious finished product. The top-heavy house of
cards, built on an illusion of rich-and-waiting customers, topples over.
So as Atif Mian and his colleague Ernest Liu started thinking this through, what did they find?
Imagine a town in which two hotels are competing for business, one
part of a giant chain and one that is independent… When interest rates
fall to very low levels, though, the payoff for being the industry
leader rises, under the logic that a business generating a given flow of
cash is more valuable when rates are low than when they are high. (This
is why low interest rates typically cause the stock market to rise.)
A market leader has more to gain from investing and becoming bigger,
and it becomes less likely that the laggards will ever catch up.
“At low interest rates, the valuation of market leaders rises
relative to the rest,” Mr. Mian said. “Amazon becomes a lot more
valuable as interest rates fall relative to a smaller player in the same
industry, and that gives a huge advantage to Amazon.”
Got there by a slightly different route, but you still got there.
The best part comes next:
The researchers tested the theory against historical stock market
data since 1962, and found that falling interest rates indeed correlated
with market leaders that outperformed the laggards.
That’s right. This empirical validation of the Austrian view had been sitting there waiting to be acknowledged for decades:
“There’s a view that we can solve all of our problems by just making
interest rates low enough,” Mr. Mian said. “We’re questioning that
notion and believe there is something else going on.”
Indeed."
See
Low Interest Rates, Market Power, and Productivity Growth by Ernest Liu, Atif Mian & Amir Sufi. Here is the abstract:
"How does the production side of the economy respond to a low interest
rate environment? This study provides a new theoretical result that low
interest rates encourage market concentration by giving industry leaders
a strategic advantage over followers, and this effect strengthens as
the interest rate approaches zero. The model provides a unified
explanation for why the fall in long-term interest rates has been
associated with rising market concentration, reduced business dynamism, a
widening productivity-gap between industry leaders and followers, and
slower productivity growth. Support for the model’s key mechanism is
established by showing that a decline in the ten year Treasury yield
generates positive excess returns for industry leaders, and the
magnitude of the excess returns rises as the Treasury yield approaches
zero."
See
How Low Interest Rates Can Freeze the Economy by David Harrison of The WSJ. Excerpt:
"Imagine you’re the owner of a small restaurant and you’re thinking of
expanding. If interest rates are high, you might think twice. When
rates fall, you might be more willing to borrow to grow your business.
But the big chain restaurant down the street also borrows at
similarly low rates to fund a much larger expansion that could steal
your customers and perhaps put you out of business.
Over the past two decades or so that phenomenon has been playing out
across industries, making the overall economy less dynamic, according to new research by economists Ernest Liu and Atif Mian of Princeton University, and Amir Sufi of the University of Chicago’s Booth School of Business.
When interest rates fall, they find, the big players in an industry
can take advantage to a far greater extent than their smaller
counterparts. That allows them to grow faster and become more
productive, but it also makes it harder for everybody else to keep up.
Over time, the smaller players get discouraged and stop investing in
new products or technologies. And the leaders become so big that they’re
no longer vulnerable to competition. They also pull back from
investing. With market power increasingly concentrated in a few big
firms, fewer entrepreneurs will decide to open new businesses."
"Under the framework outlined by the researchers, it can take decades
for lower rates to make an economy less dynamic. In fact, they find that
growth quickens in the early years before slowing down.
That’s because when interest rates first start falling, smaller firms
will borrow aggressively and invest to try to catch up to their bigger
rivals, speeding up productivity growth.
That’s what happened in the 1990’s. A decline in interest rates, as
measured by the 10-year Treasury yield, led big and small firms to
invest. Productivity growth averaged 2.2% a year in the 1990’s and 2.8%
in the 2000’s.
But around 2003, productivity growth started to slow even though
interest rates kept falling. That’s roughly when the smaller players
gave up catching up with the leaders, Mr. Sufi said."
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.