skip to main |
skip to sidebar
Why Wal-Mart can NOT afford to pay workers a $15 minimum wage
By Michael Saltsman, research director at the Employment Policies Institute.
"Can large corporations afford a $15 minimum wage better than small businesses?
Despite the fact that roughly half
of the minimum wage workforce is employed at businesses with fewer than
100 employees, corporations such as Wal-Mart have been used as the poster child in the case for a much higher wage floor.
This claim rests on three talking
points: These companies sell billions of dollars of retail goods or food
products; their CEOs are typically paid a lot of money; and the higher
pay will help get their employees off government programs.
None of these justifications survive careful scrutiny.
Wal-Mart is "hugely profitable,"
writes the National Employment Law Project (NELP) in a recent
commentary, generating "$482 billion in revenue in fiscal year 2016."
Here, the writer falsely equates revenue (the money a company takes in
before subtracting expenses) and profit (how much a company makes after
it pays its costs). It's a common tactic used to shock readers and
inflate the perception of a company's finances.
Wal-Mart's actual profit, according
to SEC filings, was only 3 percent of its total revenue. That works out
to roughly $6,400 dollars in profit for each of the company's 2.3
million employees—a profit that could be wiped out with a $15 minimum
wage.
Labor advocates are also fond of
appealing to their readers' sense of fairness by arguing that CEO pay at
the company proves it can afford a $15 minimum wage. But the math here
also doesn't add up. Wal-Mart CEO Doug McMillon earned a combined $19.4
million compensation package in 2015, including salary, stock options,
and other perks. That makes for a dramatic sound bite. But if this money
was somehow divided between all 2.3 million Wal-Mart associates, each
associate would get a one-time $8.43 bonus—that's it.
The fights for $15 have even tried
to appeal to conservative hearts by arguing that the higher pay
requirement will reduce employees' need for public support programs.
It's debatable whether this argument is offered in good faith:
California Assemblyman Kevin McCarty (D., Sacramento) recently let slip
his mask of concern for the taxpayer when he and his fellow legislators
pushed to raise the income thresholds for a public program so that
recipients of the state's new $15 minimum wage could still qualify for
state benefits. So much for ending welfare as we know it.
More importantly, the data doesn't
support this notion of a taxpayer windfall following minimum wage
increases. In a report last year, Joseph Sabia and Thanh Tam Nguyen of
San Diego State University examined 35 years of government data across a
number of different datasets. Their results suggest that, on net,
minimum wage increases have little to no ameliorating effect on
participation in (or spending on) a range of means-tested programs.
(Part of the reason lies in the fact that a majority of working-age
adults in poverty don't have jobs; more importantly, as some of the
working poor get a raise, others see their hours or jobs cut as
employers adjust to consumers' reluctance to absorb price increases.)
When the best data doesn't support
the case for $15, the UC Berkley Center for Labor Research and
Education is on hand to fill in the gaps. Indeed, the work of this
union-funded research unit has been used by advocates in almost all
recent minimum wage debates. An Albany Times-Union exposé from earlier
this year gives some indication as to why. Reviewing hundreds of pages
of emails obtained using a public records request, the paper reported
that labor advocates often work hand-in-glove with the Berkeley team
that is supposedly a neutral source of information.
The drive for a $15 minimum wage
relies primarily on popular momentum, and not the strength of the
movement's evidence. A 2015 University of New Hampshire survey of
prominent economists found that nearly three-quarters oppose a broad
minimum wage mandate of $15 per hour, and five out of six surveyed
economists believe it would have negative effects on youth employment
levels.
This economic consensus in
opposition to the "Fight for $15" won't convince organized labor and its
allies to stop promoting the policy—but it should convince policymakers
to stop listening to them."
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.