See
Ban the Box or Require the Box? by Alex Tabarrok of Marginal Revolution.
"Ban the box policies forbid employers from asking about a criminal
record on a job application. Ban the box policies don’t forbid employers
from running criminal background checks they only forbid employers from
asking about criminal history at the application/interview stage. The
policies are supposed to give people with a criminal background a
better shot at a job. Since blacks are more likely to have a criminal
history than whites, the policies are supposed to especially increase
black employment.
One potential problem with these laws is that employers may
adjust their behavior in response. In particular, since blacks are more
likely than whites to have a criminal history, a simple, even if
imperfect, substitute for not interviewing people who have a criminal
history is to not interview blacks. Employers can’t ask about race on a
job application but black and white names are distinctive enough so that
based on name alone, one can guess with a high probability of being
correct whether an applicant is black or white. In an important and impressive new paper, Amanda Agan and Sonja Starr examine how employers respond to ban the box.
Agan and Starr sent out approximately 15,000 fake job applications to
employers in New York and New Jersey. Otherwise identical applications
were randomized across distinctively black and white (male) names. Half
the applications were sent just before and another half sent just after
ban the box policies took effect. Not all firms used the box even when
legal so Agan and Starr use a powerful triple-difference strategy to
estimate causal effects (the black-white difference in callback rates
between stores that did and did not use the box before and after the
law).
Agan and Starr find that banning the box significantly increases racial discrimination in callbacks.
One can see the basic story in the situation before ban the box went
into effect. Employers who asked about criminal history used that
information to eliminate some applicants and this necessarily affected
blacks more since they are more likely to have a criminal history. But
once the applicants with a criminal history were removed, “box”
employers called back blacks and whites for interviews at equal rates.
In other words, the box leveled the playing field for applicants without
a criminal history.
Employers who didn’t use the box did something simpler but more
nefarious–they offered blacks fewer callbacks compared to otherwise
identical whites, regardless of criminal history. Together the results
suggest that employers use distinctively black names to statistically
discriminate.
When the box is banned it’s no longer possible to cheaply level the
playing field so more employers begin to statistically discriminate by
offering fewer callbacks to blacks. As a result, banning the box may
benefit black men with criminal records but it comes at the expense of
black men without records who, when the box is banned, no longer have an
easy way of signaling that they don’t have a criminal record. Sadly, a
policy that was intended to raise the employment prospects of black men
ends up having the biggest positive effect on white men with a criminal
record.
Agan and Starr suggest one possible innovation–blind employers to
names. I think that is the wrong lesson to draw. Agan and Starr look at
callbacks but what we really care about is jobs. You can blind employers
to names in initial applications but employers learn about race
eventually. Moreover, there are many other margins for employers to
adjust. Employers, for example, could simply start increasing the number
of employees they put through (post-interview) criminal background
checks.
Policies like ban the box try to get people to do the “right thing”
by blinding people to certain types of information. But blinded people
tend to use other cues to achieve their interests and when those other
cues are less informative that often makes things worse.
Rather than ban the box a plausibly better policy would be to require the box.
Requiring all employers to ask about criminal history would tend to
hurt anyone with a criminal record but it could also level racial
differences among those without a criminal record. One can, of course,
argue either side of that tradeoff and that is my point.
More generally, instead of blinding employers a better idea is to
change real constraints. At the same time as governments are forcing
employers to ban the box, for example, they are passing occupational licensing laws which often forbid employers
from hiring workers with criminal records. Banning the box and
simultaneously forbidding employers from hiring workers with criminal
records illustrates the incoherence of public policy in an
interest-group driven system.
Ban the box is another example of good intentions gone awry
because the man of system tries to arrange people as if they were pieces
on a chessboard, without understanding that:
…in the great chess-board of human society, every single
piece has a principle of motion of its own, altogether different from
that which the legislature might chuse to impress upon it. If those two
principles coincide and act in the same direction, the game of human
society will go on easily and harmoniously, and is very likely to be
happy and successful. If they are opposite or different, the game will
go on miserably, and the society must be at all times in the highest
degree of disorder. (Adam Smith, ToMS)
Addendum 1: The Agan and Starr paper
has much more of interest. Agan and Starr, find, for example, evidence
of discrimination going beyond that associated with statistical
discrimination and crime. In particular, whites are more likely to be
hired in white neighborhoods and blacks are more likely to be hired in
black neighborhoods.
Addendum 2: Agan was my former student at GMU. Her undergraduate paper (!), Sex Offender Registries: Fear without Function?, was published in the Journal of Law and Economics."
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.