Evaluating the free market by comparing it to the alternatives (We don't need more regulations, We don't need more price controls, No Socialism in the courtroom, Hey, White House, leave us all alone)
Saturday, May 12, 2018
Government Policy Mistakes Led to the Great Recession
By Peter Ireland and Darko Oračić. Peter Ireland is a Professor of Economics at Boston College and a
member of the Shadow Open Market Committee. Darko Oračić is an economic
analyst at the Croatian Employment Service.
"Most analysts agree that a housing boom and bust were the main
precipitating factor behind the deep economic crisis, now known as the
Great Recession, which took place a decade ago. And while there is no
universal consensus on what caused the housing boom and bust, these
events have, understandably, sparked many economists’ interest in
theories that financial market imperfections allow for excessive
volatility in asset prices that then lead to major fluctuations in
aggregate output and employment. Like older Keynesian theories, these
new models typically suggest that government policy intervention is
needed to curb risk-taking in financial markets and, more generally, to
counteract swings in consumer and business sentiment.
A few other economists, however, have described channels through
which government policies themselves may have created, or at least
amplified, the large fluctuations in home construction and prices that
preceded the Great Recession. These alternative theories suggest
instead that price movements generally operate, within a free market
system, to stabilize the economy when it is hit by disturbances to
aggregate supply and demand. Large disruptions to economic activity
occur only when policy mistakes work against the price system,
transforming what would otherwise be mild cyclical fluctuations into
more extreme booms and crashes. Here, we outline some arguments and
evidence to support this view, that the Great Recession was not the
inevitable consequence of unstable asset markets but followed, instead,
from a series of unfortunate government policy mistakes.
In a 2007 paper
presented at the Kansas City Fed’s Jackson Hole Symposium, John Taylor
of Stanford University presented evidence of a strong statistical
connection between data on housing starts and the federal funds rate
over the decade leading up to the crisis. Because the federal funds
rate is the interest rate under the most direct control of the Federal
Reserve, this correlation points to monetary policy as a potentially
destabilizing force during the boom-bust episode.
Some economists question this interpretation of the data, arguing
that the short-term interest rates under the Fed’s control have little
connection to the longer-term mortgages that finance the purchase of new
homes. A 2010 New York Fed working paper,
however, explains that banks and other mortgage providers borrow funds
on a short-term basis to make longer-term loans. Their activities open a
channel through which policy-induced movements in short-term rates
strongly affect the profitability of lending and thereby affect the
mortgage and housing markets.
Other statistical indicators of housing-sector activity display
strikingly strong correlations with the federal funds rate. The first
figure below shows that rapid growth in residential investment over the
period from 2003 through 2005 was preceded by very low settings for the
federal funds rate. Then, a sharp decline in residential investment in
2007 and 2008 followed a period of higher federal funds rates. The
second figure displays a similar inverse correlation between lagged
values of the federal funds rate and subsequent changes in the
Case-Shiller home price index. These correlations are consistent with traditional accounts of the
manner and timing with which monetary policy disturbances affect
economic activity. Unusually accommodative policy leads, first, to an
“overheated” economy, as artificially low interest rates encourage
excessive spending on durable goods and, later, to higher rates of price
inflation. Conversely, overly-tight policy that keeps interest rates
too high works initially to choke off capital spending and subsequently
to lower inflation.
Of course, other forces were also at work during the housing cycle of 2003 through 2008. A very recent article
on the government sponsored agencies argues that federal subsidies to
mortgage borrowing and lending, offered through the now-bankrupt Fannie
Mae and Freddie Mac, introduced volatility and fragility into the U.S.
housing market before the crisis. Nevertheless, the correlations shown
in the graphs suggest that a prolonged episode of monetary policy that
was at first too accommodative and then too tight at least contributed
to and may even have been one of the principal causes behind the housing
boom and bust that led to the Great Recession.
Future research by economists, historians, and political scientists
will undoubtedly sharpen – and may even change – our view of what caused
the Great Recession. At present, however, our best bet is that the
crisis was not the inevitable consequence of inherent instability in US
asset markets. Rather, both the recession and housing crisis that
preceded it appear to have been the unintended consequences of
government policies that interfered with the workings of the price
system and destabilized what would otherwise have been much more
efficient markets."
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.