"While federal regulatory reform is critical, it’s equally important that existing oversight laws be followed. Unfortunately, many of these laws are routinely disregarded, with little consequence.
We at CEI often point to the fact that no one really knows how many federal agencies exist. A new report from the Government Accountability Office (GAO) emphasizes a related problem: we also don’t know how many federal spending programs exist either, despite a 2011 law requiring a comprehensive inventory from the Office of Management and Budget (OMB). Recent national defense authorization legislation, GAO notes, has given OMB until January 2025 to comply.
We also often point to a growing fusion between spending and regulation, so this lapse by OMB is troublesome to say the least. Unfortunately, skepticism is warranted with respect to the thoroughness of OMB’s upcoming inventory. OMB’s track record on compliance with regulatory oversight laws is also poor, as I detail in a new column at Forbes, and Congress has been largely indifferent to holding them accountable. Consider the following:
The Regulatory Right-to-Know Act mandates an annual report to Congress on the benefits and costs of major rules. However, these reports are consistently overdue and incomplete. The most recent, covering fiscal years 2020-22, was published in early 2024. Most glaringly, the requirement for an aggregate cost estimate for federal regulations have been ignored since the early 2000s, leaving little transparency about the cumulative burden of the administrative state.
The Paperwork Reduction Act also suffers from neglect. The Information Collection Budget (ICB) required by the Act has been sporadically published in recent years, with several delayed editions appearing in 2023. The latest ICB shifts focus away from reducing paperwork burdens toward increasing access to government benefits (of the very sort OMB neglects to thoroughly inventory, conveniently enough)—neglecting its original purpose. Additionally, the annual “Paperwork Burden Accounting” roundup, which traditionally documented over 10 billion hours of paperwork, is conspicuously absent from the latest edition. We did inquire, but it remains unaddressed:
The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA), intended to ease small business burdens, is also often ignored. A 2024 report from the House Small Business Committee found that agencies frequently misclassify rules to bypass RFA analysis and underestimate the impact on small businesses. They also fail to assess whether new rules duplicate existing regulations, resulting in unnecessary burdens.
The Congressional Review Act, designed to give Congress a window to review and disapprove major rules, is also underutilized. Despite thousands of rules being issued since its passage, fewer than two dozen have been overturned. But elements of it are also unlawfully disregarded. Some major rules are not properly submitted to GAO and to both houses of Congress, which raises questions about their validity.
There are a couple recent laws that could improve matters that I discuss in the Forbes article, such a 2023 law that Biden signed requiring 100-word summaries to accompany rules in the Federal Register, and one just signed this month (the GAO Database Modernization Act, to supplement GAO’s database by requiring agencies to notify GAO whenever a rule is revoked, suspended, replaced, amended, or otherwise made ineffective.
These two developments represent a silver lining on a dark regulatory cloud. Congress needs to remain vigilant that they do not lapse in the manner of their predecessors. Addressing widespread noncompliance with regulatory oversight laws should be a priority in the coming months and years as the 118th Congress enters its final weeks.
For more, see Forbes, “Exposing Loopholes: How Federal Regulatory Oversight Laws Are Being Ignored.”"
Thursday, October 31, 2024
The compliance crisis: Unveiling the regulatory loopholes agencies love
The robustness of coal?
"Coal consumption in 2030 is now estimated 6% higher than only a year ago. That may sound small, but it amounts to adding the equivalent of the consumption of Japan, the world’s fourth-largest coal burner. By 2030, the IEA now believes coal consumption will remain higher than it was back in 2010…
One notable statistic: Two-thirds of the total increase in energy demand in 2023 was met by fossil fuels, according to the IEA.
Here is more from Javier Blas at Bloomberg. Via Nicanor."
Minimum Wage Laws are UNemployment Laws
"The minimum wage law is a snare and a delusion. It preys upon the weakest economic actors in the land. Before the advent of this pernicious law way back in the 1930s, the unemployment rate of whites and blacks, young and old, was about the same. There were no marked differences regarding joblessness for any of these categories. Nowadays, the unemployment rate of teenaged blacks is quadruple, yes, quadruple, that of middle aged whites.
Why is this?
The law is an unemployment law, not an employment law. It mandates that anyone with a productivity level below that stipulated by law will be unemployable. If the law requires a wage of $10 per hour, and your productivity is only $7 hourly, then any firm foolish enough to hire you will effectively lose $3 every 60 minutes. Either they will not hire you, or, they will go broke if they do that once too often. Raising the level from $10 to $15 will just mean that those with a productivity of $13, who could have worked with a law requiring salaries of $10, can no longer do so.
The minimum wage law is thus not a floor which when raised boosts compensation to labor. No, rather, it is a high jump bar that the worker needs to exceed in order to get a job in the first place. The higher is it raised, the harder it is to jump over, into employment. If it really were floor, undergirding wages, why not boost it to $100 per hour, or better yet $1000? Then, we’d all be rich. Why not cut off all foreign aid to poor countries, and tell them, instead, to institute a minimum wage law, and keep raising its level until national poverty were ended?
Bernie Sanders wants to raise the minimum wage level to $17 per hour. That is more than double the present federal level of $7.25. Does he want to move black teen unemployment rates up from quadruple that of middle aged whites to quintuple? To sextuple? To septuple levels? (True confession: I had to look up these words). Presumably not. What, then, is the explanation for his stance? Economic illiteracy.
All too often, research on this matter focuses on increases in the minimum wage level. Who cares about mere increases? The entire rotten law ought to be repealed, and salt sown where once it stood. For at any level, it makes it impossible for those whose productivity is below the level stipulated by law. Card and Krueger [1] would disagree. They found that a slight increase in its level in New Jersey did not lead to more unemployment of the unskilled than in neighboring Pennsylvania, which did not raise its mandated legal wage. But their statistics were proven to be unreliable, and, in any case, we should be comparing the law with its absence, not with a slightly higher or lower level.
Fire burns people. It does so at 150 degrees Fahrenheit, as well as at 152 degrees. Suppose a chemist cannot discern much of a difference between these two temperatures, and then concludes that there is nothing wrong with burning people. What should we say to him? We should aver that there is something seriously wrong with his analysis. We should respond to the Cards and Kruegers of the world in much the same manner.
[1] Notable supporters of minimum wage legislation are Card and Krueger, 1994, 2000. For critiques, see Block, 2001; Burkhauser, Couch and Wittenburg, David, 1996; Burkhauser and Finnegan, 1989; Gallaway and Adie, 1995; Hamermesh and Welch, 1995; Neumark and Wascher, 2000."
Wednesday, October 30, 2024
More Childcare Regulations Equal Fewer Babies, Study Finds
By Michael Tennant of The New American.
"States with more-restrictive childcare regulations have lower fertility rates than states with less-restrictive ones in part because stricter regulations drive up the cost of childcare, according to a recent study from West Virginia University’s (WVU) Knee Regulatory Research Center.
“Childcare workers and parents bear the weight of licensing regulations and administrative costs,” study co-author Anna Claire Flowers, a PhD fellow at George Mason University’s Mercatus Center, said in a statement to the Daily Caller. “High-quality care is the goal, but some measures have been shown to boost prices much more than quality.”
The Daily Caller reported that “childcare costs rose nationally by 32% from 2019 to 2023, outpacing the 20% rise in overall prices within that same time frame.”
For this reason, many consider childcare “a ‘classic’ example of market failure,” the report explains, and thus demand “greater intervention in the form of subsidies” to offset the higher costs. “However,” continues the report,
a subsidy approach misses the key role that the regulatory environment of the childcare market plays in raising costs. Though well-intended, the regulatory framework cripples progress towards affordability, availability, flexibility, and quality for American families seeking childcare solutions.
Nanny States
The authors created a childcare regulation index that ranks states on a zero-to-10 scale on the basis of their childcare regulations, with zero being the most restrictive and 10 being the least restrictive. The states with the lowest rankings are, not surprisingly, clustered primarily in liberal New England, though a few Great Lakes-area states including Tim Walz’s Minnesota also have highly restrictive childcare regulations. The states with the greatest childcare freedom are mostly in the South and the West. The freest state for childcare is Louisiana, with an index of 9.08, while Massachusetts came in dead last at just 1.73.
The rankings considered 17 variables in four major categories of regulation: “group size and staff-child ratios by age range” and “training hours and educational requirements by position.” New York, for example, requires childcare facilities to have one staff member for every eight pre-kindergarten children, while North Carolina, at the other end of the spectrum, allows up to 20 kids per instructor. “Illinois requires preschool teachers to have a high school diploma and 60 college credit hours, plus additional training and experience to become licensed, whereas other states only require a GED,” notes the study. Virginia, meanwhile, mandates “75 square feet of outdoor space per child,” a third of which “must be shaded playground space with shock-absorbent surfacing.”
According to the authors:
These indicators … are also poor indicators of true quality. Rather, they are the only “proxies” that regulators can objectively set. In contrast, through repeated interactions, parents are generally able to determine the value and level of quality on harder to evaluate metrics. However, these easy-to-observe metrics for regulators that do not correlate well with actual quality drive up cost[s] considerably. Childcare providers must invest in meeting the regulatory standards, which can involve hiring more staff, obtaining certifications, upgrading facilities, or purchasing specialized equipment. These compliance costs are typically passed on to parents through higher fees…. In other words, regulation[s] tighten the supply of services in ways that drive up prices[,] which fuels the affordability concerns.
Expensive? No Kidding!
Faced with higher costs for childcare, it is only natural that couples should curtail their childbearing. The authors found this to be the case by comparing each state’s ranking to its “fertility gap,” the difference between the “replacement rate” of 2.1 births per woman and the state’s actual fertility rate:
The inverse relationship between regulation and fertility can be observed … in some states. The New England region generally demonstrates low index scores (most restrictive regulation) and above average fertility gaps. In our work, we find that a one-point increase in the childcare regulation index (toward more childcare freedom) is associated with a reduction of the fertility gap by 0.025 to 0.029 children.
If Massachusetts’ childcare regulations were to become as loose as Louisiana’s, its fertility rate would increase by 14 percent, the authors assert. And, they add, if all states became as free as Louisiana with regard to childcare, 14 states’ fertility rates would exceed 1.9 births per woman, and two would even exceed the replacement rate.
“While not the only major player, childcare regulation is one piece of the policy puzzle that can make it more or less difficult for families to find compatibility between work responsibilities and raising children,” Flowers told the Daily Caller.
That, in turn, has a direct bearing on how many children are born. Another study cited by the authors concluded:
Where the two [career and family] are easy to combine, many women have both a career and multiple children, resulting in high fertility and high female labor force participation. When career and family goals are in conflict, fewer women work and fewer babies are born.
Vance Virtually Vindicated
By implication, the WVU study vindicates Ohio Senator J.D. Vance’s much-mocked suggestion that car-seat regulations are to some degree responsible for America’s falling birthrate. The more rules that manufacturers must follow — and thus the more they must charge for their products — and the more advanced the age at which children are forced to ride in car seats, the more expensive having children becomes. The more expensive having children becomes, the less of it there will be. As with childcare regulations, car-seat regulations don’t explain the entire birthrate decline, but they undoubtedly play a part in it."
Feds Admit Fossil Fuels Are Still the Cheapest
A Department of Energy analysis found natural gas is the cheapest residential energy source on the market
"The International Energy Agency (IEA) has released its 2024 World Energy Outlook, an annual market forecast regarded as the authoritative standard for global energy analysis. This year's report predicts that fossil fuel demand will peak by 2030, that clean energy sources will generate more than half of the world's energy by the end of the decade, and that global energy prices will decline as traditional energy use phases out.
As many cheered the IEA's report, the U.S. Department of Energy (DOE) quickly tempered expectations with its own study identifying natural gas as the cheapest residential energy source available. Electricity (energy derived from an electrical current rather than a pipeline) was the most expensive, costing 3.5 times more than natural gas. In real-world terms, households that heat their homes with electricity this winter will pay 75 percent more than those that use natural gas.
The DOE's report tells an inconvenient truth that many governments, including the Biden administration, want to ignore: Fossil fuels are cheap, abundant, and critical to meeting the world's energy needs. Restricting access to these sources will increase costs for consumers, stifle global economic development, and do little to curb greenhouse gas emissions.
Fossil fuels meet more than 80 percent of global energy demand, a dominant position that they will likely hold as emerging economies become more industrialized. As people become more prosperous, they will be able to transition away from heating and cooking with dung, which is estimated to prematurely kill 3.7 million people per year through indoor air pollution. Higher levels of wealth allow societies to focus on basic needs, such as sanitation and infrastructure.
Forcing countries to use more expensive forms of energy will keep poor nations poor and hurt industrialized ones too.
In the U.S., consumers are beginning to feel the impacts of state and federal policies that favor certain technologies over cost and reliability. In July, PJM Interconnection, the organization that regulates electricity in the Midwest and Mid-Atlantic regions, announced it was increasing its rates by more than 800 percent. Dwindling supply is driving these cost increases: Baseload power sources have been forced to close because of state-implemented green energy mandates and steep demand forecasts from electric vehicles and data centers.
The U.S. electric grid is not the only one experiencing supply shortfalls. The European Union (E.U.) is expecting total electricity consumption to rise by 60 percent through 2030. To meet demand, the E.U. says it needs to invest 584 billion euros ($632 billion) by the end of the decade. The IEA, meanwhile, projects global consumption will increase by as much as 34 percent. Without access to abundant and affordable energy, consumers will be left paying more for less reliable electricity.
The steep cost of government preferences for renewable energy sources will come with negligible environmental benefits. European countries whose penchant for solar and wind led to the forced closure of nuclear power plants are increasingly turning to coal to provide backup generation when the sun isn't shining and wind isn't blowing.
While the IEA's utopian world may seem nice, the DOE's report shows that natural gas is still the most affordable energy source available. A rushed transition to renewable sources will increase energy costs while hurting grid reliability and economic mobility."
Tuesday, October 29, 2024
The University of Michigan Doubled Down on D.E.I. What Went Wrong?
A decade and a quarter of a billion dollars later, students and faculty are more frustrated than ever
By Nicholas Confessore of The NY Times. Excerpts:
"Most students must take at least one class addressing “racial and ethnic intolerance and resulting inequality.” Doctoral students in educational studies must take an “equity lab” and a racial-justice seminar. Computer-science students are quizzed on microaggressions."
"Michigan’s largest division trains professors in “antiracist pedagogy” and dispenses handouts on “Identifying and Addressing Characteristics of White Supremacy Culture,” like “worship of the written word.” The engineering school promises a “pervasive education around issues of race, ethnicity, unconscious bias and inclusion.”
At the art museum, captions for an exhibit of American and European art attest to histories of oppression “even in works that may not appear to have any direct relation to these histories.” The English department has adopted a 245-word land acknowledgment, describing its core subject as “a language brought by colonizers to North America.” Even Michigan’s business school, according to its D.E.I. web page, is committed to fighting “all forms of oppression.”"
"Michigan has poured roughly a quarter of a billion dollars into D.E.I. since 2016"
"Tens of thousands of undergraduates have completed bias training. Thousands of instructors have been trained in inclusive teaching."
"some of Michigan’s peer institutions have soured on aspects of D.E.I. Last spring, both the Massachusetts Institute of Technology and Harvard’s Faculty of Arts and Sciences said they would no longer require job candidates to submit diversity statements; such “compelled statements,” M.I.T.’s president said, “impinge on freedom of expression.”"
"Michigan hasn’t joined the retreat. Instead, it has redoubled its efforts"
"the number of employees who work in D.E.I.-related offices or have “diversity,” “equity” or “inclusion” in their job titles increased by 70 percent, reaching 241, according to figures compiled by Mark J. Perry"
"I found a different kind of backlash building, one that emanated not from Washington or right-wing think tanks but from inside the university’s own dorms and faculty lounges. On Michigan’s largely left-leaning campus, few of the people I met questioned the broad ideals of diversity or social justice. Yet the most common attitude I encountered about D.E.I. during my visits to Ann Arbor was a kind of wary disdain."
"many Black students today regard the school’s expansive program as a well-meaning failure. The university now has a greater proportion of Hispanic, Asian and first-generation students and a more racially diverse staff. But in a state where 14 percent of residents are Black, the school’s Black undergraduate enrollment has long hovered stubbornly at around 4 percent"
"On campus, I met students with a wide range of backgrounds and perspectives. Not one expressed any particular enthusiasm for Michigan’s D.E.I. initiative. Where some found it shallow, others found it stifling. They rolled their eyes at the profusion of course offerings that revolve around identity and oppression, the D.E.I.-themed emails they frequently received but rarely read."
"the school has also become less inclusive: In a survey released in late 2022, students and faculty members reported a less positive campus climate than at the program’s start and less of a sense of belonging. Students were less likely to interact with people of a different race or religion or with different politics"
"Everyday campus complaints and academic disagreements, professors and students told me, were now cast as crises of inclusion and harm, each demanding some further administrative intervention or expansion."
"As the “diversity rationale” spread throughout academia and business, according to the scholar Frederick R. Lynch, the notion of diversity as a form of reparations began to broaden and blur. Schools now needed diversity to prepare citizens for America’s multicultural future; corporations needed diversity to serve an increasingly global customer base."
"Drawing on a growing body of post-Bakke research, school experts argued that students not only learned “in deeper, more complex ways” in a diverse setting but also emerged better equipped to thrive in a multiracial democracy"
"D.E.I. research flourished throughout academia, making the case that schools could harvest the benefits of diversity only if they intervened decisively in campus life and the classroom."
"Over the four decades following Bakke, according to a recent study from the Progressive Policy Institute, the ranks of full-time college administrators increased more than twice as fast as student enrollment. Their primary job was to enhance “student life” — and attract more customers."
"The Ann Arbor campus grew to have nearly 16,000 nonfaculty employees, more than twice the number of full-time faculty members."
"These growing bureaucracies represented a major — and profoundly left-leaning — reshuffling of campus power. Administrators were even more politically liberal than faculty members"
"They promulgated what Lyell Asher, a professor of English at Lewis & Clark College in Oregon, has called “an alternate curriculum,” taught not in classrooms but in dorms, disciplinary hearings and orientation programs."
"The former president of one top research institution recalled for me how students once came to his office with demands, presented in a kind of theatrical performance, to enhance the university’s D.E.I. program. The former president, who asked for anonymity for fear of risking his present job, later learned that some of the program’s senior staff members had worked with and encouraged the students to pressure the administration on their behalf."
[D.E.I. 1.0] "The initial planning ultimately yielded nearly 2,000 “action items” across campus — a tribute to Michigan’s belief in the power of bureaucratic process to promote change. “It’s important to focus on our standard operating procedures and worry less about attitudes,” said Sellers [psychologist Robert M. Sellers], who was appointed Michigan’s first chief diversity officer. “Attitudes will follow.”"
"In the year or so after Trump took office, the school’s Bias Response Team examined more than 150 student complaints, sometimes confronting students or faculty members over supposedly offensive classroom comments or social media posts. It was unclear if Michigan was, in fact, becoming a more hateful place. A lawsuit filed by Speech First, a conservative advocacy group, charged that Michigan was subjecting students to expansive, subjective definitions of harassment and bias"
"Other administrators and D.E.I. leads, however, found Sellers’s program a distraction from such work. Some felt that the monthly meetings Sellers’s office convened were overly focused on the process of writing plans and reports. One-on-one discussion with his deputies could have the feel of a box-checking exercise. “I would put on a good show,” said one former dean, herself a woman of color. “I would say, ‘We had meetings with students, we did this, we did that, we made posters.’ We were jumping through hoops, and that’s what they wanted to see.” Like other current and former deans, she asked to remain anonymous because, as she put it, “no one can criticize the D.E.&I. program — not its scale, its dominance.”
On their private text-messaging group, deans across the university grumbled about the mountains of data they were required to submit each year. Their public progress reports and D.E.I. strategic plans were heavily vetted by the university counsel’s office and Sellers’s team; the resulting public documents, though meant to ensure accountability, were often both lengthy and vague. “No one knew what they were supposed to be doing,” the former dean said. “And no one would tell us. But we had to show that we were doing something.”
At the same time, Sellers and his allies began building what amounted to a parallel hiring system, giving them a more direct role in reshaping Michigan’s faculty. Proposal 2 expressly prohibited racial or gender preferences in hiring. But in 2016, Michigan began a new program called the Collegiate Fellows, reserved for postdoctoral scholars “in all liberal-arts fields who are committed to diversity in the academy.” Based at the College of Literature, Science and the Arts, Michigan’s largest division, the program provided additional budget dollars with each fellow hired, a further incentive to department chairs."
"out of the 49 new faculty members subsequently hired through the program, 80 percent were people of color, according to a university spokeswoman. (In an interview last year, Chavous put the total even higher.) Their research interests included “the epistemic exclusion of diverse practitioners within the academy,” critical food studies and how Indian transgender activists “appropriate normative U.S.-centric conceptions of gender rights as human rights.”"
"it was almost universally understood among professors I spoke with that these programs were intended to generate racial and gender diversity without explicitly using affirmative action"
"Professors across the university described to me how, in faculty meetings and on search committees, they had resigned themselves to a pervasive double-think around hiring."
"By the spring of 2020, Michigan was reaching the final stage of its first 5-year D.E.I. plan. But in the wake of George Floyd’s murder by a white Minneapolis police officer that May, as protests erupted around the country and demands to root out racism echoed from campuses to corporate offices, none of the training and programming — the money and new hires and promises — seemed to matter."
"At the law school, which had a longstanding policy of not commenting on events “outside the Quad,” students demanded a public statement about Floyd’s murder. The Black Law Students Association issued further demands, including mandatory antiracism training, more mental health counseling and the hiring of a professor in critical race theory."
"D.E.I. consultants, Jerry Kang and Devon Carbado . . . invited students and faculty to share their experiences of racism and discrimination at the university. Yet for all the heated public rhetoric, people with knowledge of the discussions told me, some of the examples seemed to them relatively minor."
"a professor had asked a white student to read aloud from the landmark Supreme Court decision Cooper v. Aaron, which forced the desegregation of public schools in Little Rock, Ark. The 1958 decision contained the term “Negro,” which some students said was offensive."
"In early 2021, the entire law faculty was invited to a session provided through Michigan’s Spectrum Center, which serves the school’s L.G.B.T.Q. community. Many professors joined the Zoom, desperate for help navigating classroom moments that had become dangerously charged. Instead, the session was devoted to gender terminology, pronoun usage and sexual identity. The facilitator urged them to require students to declare their preferred pronouns and furnished a list of dozens of sexual orientations, some of which professors told me they had never heard of. Instead of asking students about their sexuality, they were advised, faculty should ask students to specify their “attractionality.”"
"That September, the department convened a workshop led by Whitney Peoples, then the coordinator for critical race pedagogies at Michigan’s in-house teaching consultancy, known as the Center for Research on Learning & Teaching. The workshop was titled “Teaching Texts That Contain Racist Language,” but according to one person who attended, Peoples argued that literary works containing slurs should almost never be assigned in the first place."
"In 2015, the university office charged with enforcing federal civil rights mandates like Title IX received about 200 complaints of sex- or gender-based misconduct on Michigan’s campus. By 2020, that number had more than doubled. Last year, it surpassed 500. Complaints involving race, religion or national origin increased to almost 400 from a few dozen during roughly the same period."
"in November 2022, the B.S.U. issued a scathing attack on D.E.I. 1.0 titled “More Than Four.” Despite the many millions spent on D.E.I. 1.0, the report noted, the percentage of Black students — then around 4 percent — was nearly as low as it was in 1970."
"Michigan’s all-embracing D.E.I. program was, in a sense, too inclusive. It suffered from “structural flaws” that caused it to “systematically neglect” Black students — the very people who inspired D.E.I. 1.0 in the first place. The university “actively perpetuates systemic racism and oppression,” the B.S.U. charged, by “failing to directly denounce and combat anti-Blackness.”"
"That same year [2022], Chavous was promoted to chief diversity officer, succeeding her husband, who remains a professor at Michigan. In 2023, the university announced that it would expand Chavous’s Collegiate Fellows program. It would hire even more scholars “committed to diversity in the academy.” When I asked her how many of the fellows hired so far advanced right-leaning arguments about diversity or inequity, Chavous responded that the program favored “a commitment to broadening access, to engaging in equity in one’s discipline and field. So we’re not asking about any particular ideological or political stance.”
In practice, of course, those commitments can themselves be ideological stances. In a dissenting report to the committee urging Michigan to continue requiring diversity statements in hiring, Chandra Sripada, a professor of philosophy and psychiatry, argued that asking candidates to detail how they would advance equity inevitably required them to take particular positions about contested social issues. When Sripada asked Michigan colleagues to evaluate a hypothetical diversity statement that called for de-emphasizing “the axes of identity on which we differ” in classrooms and to make admissions a “level playing field,” one of them called it “career suicide.”
Officially, Michigan’s D.E.I. plan includes a pledge to increase political diversity on campus. When I asked Chavous if there were any programs aimed at achieving that goal, she described an effort by the new dean of the Ford School for public policy to ensure that its curriculum exposed students to a range of political perspectives. By most accounts, conservatives remain a small minority at Michigan, perhaps 10 or 15 percent of all students. There had always been social pressure to conform to the prevailing liberalism there, faculty members and students told me. But it seemed to intensify as D.E.I. expanded, as if the peer pressure had a kind of institutional sanction.
In 2022, after the Supreme Court struck down Roe v. Wade, students at the medical school demanded that administrators cancel a speech by Kristin M. Collier, an internist and clinical professor there, at a ceremony welcoming new medical students. Collier directs the school’s program on health, spirituality and religion. She is also a Christian who has publicly discussed her opposition to abortion — a viewpoint the students considered disqualifying. A petition demanded that Collier, who was selected by student and faculty members of a school honor society, be replaced with someone who would inspire students “to be courageous advocates for patient autonomy and our communities.”
Though her speech went forward, Michigan assigned her a bodyguard. Security was heightened at the clinic where she delivered care."
"Michigan, she noted, had many programs that explored racial and ethnic identity, but few on religious identity, like hers."
"For a large swath of students and professors, Michigan’s D.E.I. initiatives have become simply background noise, like the rote incantations of a state religion."
"Even within the academy, though, some long-accepted precepts of D.E.I. are coming under closer scrutiny. Some researchers argue that teaching students to view the world chiefly through the lens of identity and oppression can leave them vulnerable instead of empowered. Psychologists have questioned whether implicit bias can be accurately measured or reduced through training. The notion that microaggressions are not only real but ubiquitous in interracial encounters is widespread in D.E.I. programs; a 2021 review of the microaggressions literature, however, judged it “without adequate scientific basis.”"
"Many faculty members I spoke to worried that Michigan’s press to ingrain D.E.I. into their scholarship — the diversity statements, the special fellowships, the clamor for research into contemporary social-justice issues — had narrowed its departments rather than broadening them. Disciplines and historical eras that couldn’t be jammed into an equity framework were being left to wither; even academics from minority backgrounds felt they had to present themselves as scholars of equity in order to advance."
"One recent analysis by the political scientist Kevin Wallsten found that the larger the D.E.I. bureaucracy at a university, the more discomfort students felt expressing their views on social media and in informal conversations with other students."
"even some liberal scholars believe D.E.I. looms too large. Amna Khalid, a historian at Carleton College in Minnesota, argues that modern D.E.I. is not, as some on the right hold, a triumph of critical theory or postcolonialism but of the corporatization of higher education, in which universities have tried to turn moral and political ideals into a system of formulas and dashboards. “They want a managerial approach to difference,” Khalid said. “They want no friction. But diversity inherently means friction.”"
"in the tumult that followed the Oct. 7 attacks in Israel. A spate of unsettling events unfolded in Ann Arbor, eerily echoing the racist provocations at the dawn of D.E.I. 1.0. Someone painted a red X through a Star of David on the Rock; one Jewish student found “Yall R Jewish” scrawled on her dorm whiteboard, near the mezuza affixed to her doorway. Another Star of David was scrawled on benches outside the campus Hillel, this time with an equal sign and a swastika."
"The school’s formidable bureaucracy seemed both paralyzed and heavy-handed, scorned by many students and divided against itself."
"Many Jewish students and alumni were astonished when, in January, a committee of Michigan D.E.I. leaders gave the school’s Martin Luther King Jr. Spirit Award to a pro-Palestine student group and its leader, a senior named Salma Hamamy: The group had issued a statement on Oct. 7 justifying the murder of Israeli civilians."
"This June, civil rights officials at the federal Department of Education found that Michigan had systematically mishandled student complaints over the 18-month period ending in February. Out of 67 complaints of harassment or discrimination based on national origin or ancestry that the officials reviewed — an overwhelming majority involving allegations of antisemitism, according to a tally I obtained — Michigan had investigated and made findings in just one."
"At the school of social work, some students complained that instructors were not talking enough about the unfolding war; others wanted them to weigh in less. Few felt safe talking to one another. Daicia Price, the school’s D.E.I. director and a clinical professor, was pressed to weigh in on behalf of the school. At one point, she recalled, a student lectured her that there was “a place in hell” for people who remained neutral about the war."
Monday, October 28, 2024
Harris Stops Talking About Climate Change
As the high costs of green policies hit, it’s becoming a lose-lose issue for politicians of the left
By Bjorn Lomborg. Excerpts:
"It’d be one thing to ask for sacrifices that could save the planet. But even at a whopping official price tag of $369 billion over 10 years, the Inflation Reduction Act’s climate measures as written were likely to lower the projected global temperature in 2100 by less than 0.03 degree Fahrenheit."
"The cost has rapidly ballooned to somewhere north of $3 trillion over 30 to 40 years, even as emission cuts have been slower and smaller than predicted. No wonder Ms. Harris isn’t trumpeting it."
"The truth of the matter is that nothing Ms. Harris does to cut carbon can stop climate change. It’s developing nations that are driving emissions in this century. Even if the U.S. achieved net-zero carbon emissions overnight and stayed that way for the rest of the century—basically destroying its economy and much of American quality of life—the 2100 projected global temperature would only drop 0.3 degree Fahrenheit based on the United Nations’ climate model."
Democrats Make Elon Musk’s Pay Day
‘Regulatory credits’ boost Tesla profit and its CEO’s wealth.
"Elon Musk on Thursday became billions of dollars richer after a strong earnings report caused Tesla Motors’ stock to pop. Congratulations to Democrats, whose green-energy subsidies and mandates are enriching the man they hate most after Donald Trump.
Tesla beat forecasts with a $2.2 billion profit in the third quarter, a 17% increase from a year earlier. Look under the hood, and you’ll find subsidies are driving its profits. Auto sales increased by a mere 1% compared to the same quarter last year while “regulatory credits” grew 33%. Such credits accounted for a third of its profit.
If auto makers fail to meet California’s electric-vehicle quotas or the Environmental Protection Agency’s greenhouse gas emissions standards, they must buy compliance credits from manufacturers with a surplus—namely, Tesla. More auto makers are struggling to meet these EV mandates amid slowing demand and an EV market glut.
They are scaling back EV production plans and instead buying credits from Tesla because this is less expensive than making cars at a hefty loss. Tesla says it is booking more regulatory credit sales “as other automobile manufacturers scale back on their battery electric vehicle plans.” Their EV woes are Tesla’s gain.
As EV mandates ratchet up—California requires that they [EVs] make up 68% of auto maker sales by 2030—the value of Tesla’s regulatory credits will increase. Could this be one reason Tesla is trading at two to three times the forward earnings multiple of high-flying tech stocks? Investors may be betting on rising government mandates and subsidies.
Tesla also benefits from the Inflation Reduction Act’s $7,500 per EV tax credit, which we calculate amounted to about $1.25 billion this past quarter, and consumer EV rebates in some states. Tesla says it was owed $315 million in rebates at the end of the last quarter. And don’t forget the IRA’s manufacturing tax credits for solar panels and batteries, which is Tesla’s fastest-growing and most profitable business.
These credits can offset more than a third of the cost of producing batteries for EVs and power storage units. California and other states are using Tesla batteries to back up their grids as they strive to meet climate mandates. Tesla says IRA manufacturing credits boosted its energy generation and storage margins and that it expects this business to more than double this year.
It’s amusing to hear Democrats now howl that Mr. Musk is benefiting from their government largesse. Here’s a novel idea: Scrap all climate mandates and subsidies. That way Tesla can succeed or fail on its own merit."
Cuba Can’t Keep the Lights On
The socialist model is beset by constant food and energy shortages
"In the socialist and healthcare paradise that is Cuba, the regime can’t keep the lights on. Another failure of the electricity grid struck Saturday evening and continued into Sunday, blacking out much of the island including the capital of Havana.
The country has been enduring weeks of periodic blackouts that can last for 10 to 20 hours at a time, as the Communist government struggles to provide even basic services. The regime blames deteriorating equipment, fuel shortages and rising electricity demand. It also blames the U.S. trade embargo, as it always does for every ill on the island.
But nothing stops Cuba from importing the parts it needs from the rest of the world. The real problem is a regime that can’t make much of anything work except exporting its people. Russia and Venezuela have reduced fuel sales to the island, which can’t pay its bills. Shortages of food and medicine are rampant.
Cuba’s dictatorship is a human tragedy and its people deserve much better. But they won’t get it as long as Communists run the place and enrich themselves at the expense of the people they impoverish."
Trump’s Tariffs and Economic Risk
How much would his border taxes offset his pro-growth policies?
"Donald Trump said recently that “tariff” is the most beautiful word in the dictionary, except “faith” or “love,” and in this belief he seems consistent. So it’s worth taking seriously Mr. Trump’s campaign promise to impose a universal baseline tariff of 10% or 20% on all imports to the U.S., plus 60% on China.
A first question is whether Mr. Trump really would do this, since it would dwarf his last tariffs. The average tariff rate on all U.S. imports is currently about 2%, the Tax Foundation says, and Mr. Trump’s plan could raise it to “highs not seen since the Great Depression.” That was under the infamous 1930 Smoot-Hawley tariff.
Mr. Trump started his first term with pro-growth deregulation and tax reform. He began his tariff wave in 2018, with targeted levies on steel, aluminum, washing machines, solar cells, and a variety of goods from China. He held off adding a tax of up to 35% on foreign autos, even as his Commerce Department wrote a report calling them a national-security threat.
The evidence is clear that the tariffs had real costs and reduced the growth spurred by his other policies. Other countries retaliated, hitting U.S. producers of everything from apples to whiskey. The government paid farmers billions in compensation. Harley-Davidson had to shift production for its overseas customers to Thailand to stay competitive.
There was no great boom in manufacturing employment. More jobs involve using steel than making it, and one study said higher steel prices led to 75,000 lost manufacturing jobs. Consumers paid more for many products, as companies passed on tariff costs. The economic studies on these points are copious, and it’s worrisome that Mr. Trump and his advisers dismiss them.
The next question is whether Mr. Trump has the power to impose a universal tariff. The Constitution grants Congress, not the President, authority over trade. It’s unlikely that Congress would pass a new broad-based tariff on all imports, though protectionism has been gaining support in the Trump era.
But Congress has already ceded considerable power to the President, especially provisions against “unfair” trade practices (Section 301) and “national security” threats (Section 232). Mr. Trump used these powers in his first term, and he was aggressive in exploiting 232 in particular, as he no doubt would be again.
The bigger danger is that Mr. Trump might use the International Emergency Economic Powers Act (IEEPA). This law gives the President broad authority, after declaring an emergency, “to deal with any unusual and extraordinary threat” from abroad. IEEPA has been used to freeze Venezuelan assets and stop exports to Iran. It has never been used to impose tariffs. Mr. Trump threatened Mexico with it in 2019 but stood down amid a deal to expand the “Remain in Mexico” migrant policy.
Yet it’s hard to believe Mr. Trump could legally get away with declaring all imports from everywhere an emergency to impose a tariff. That would transform IEEPA from a sanctions law into a grant of limitless presidential power over trade. Progressives love the idea of a carbon tariff. Could President Biden impose one unilaterally by declaring foreign emissions to be an emergency?
If Mr. Trump tries it, he may find himself in court, perhaps the Supreme Court. The current Justices have struck down similar efforts to abuse presidential power, such as Mr. Biden’s $400 billion student-loan forgiveness.
Mr. Trump sometimes says he sees tariffs merely as a means to gain trade reciprocity: If Japan had zero tariffs on U.S. goods, the U.S. would do the same. But the process of getting to zero is likely to be messy if it is even achievable. Once imposed, tariffs build business and union constituencies that won’t easily give them up. The current 25% U.S. tariff on foreign trucks was imposed in 1964.
Yet at other times Mr. Trump sounds like a true believer in high tariff walls for their own sake—as the way to return manufacturing to the U.S. and protect it from foreign competition. This seems to be the view of his chief trade adviser, Robert Lighthizer, and perhaps running mate JD Vance.
Known as import substitution, this model of economic growth kept India globally uncompetitive for decades. It would guarantee higher consumer prices and the slow erosion of U.S. business competitiveness. Our guess is that financial markets would signal their disapproval if Mr. Trump goes this far.
Another risk, and a special case, is trade with China. Mr. Trump’s first-term tariffs didn’t change Chinese behavior, but he seems more determined than ever to raise the stakes. China’s mercantilism and IP theft have caused foreign firms to reduce their investment in China, which is the prudent move. Strategic economic decoupling is warranted. But an all-out trade war with China would have significant costs for America too.
Mr. Trump’s overall economic agenda is superior to Kamala Harris’s model of tax, spend, mandate and regulate. But his tariff agenda is an anti-growth wild card that poses considerable economic risk in a second term. We’d have to hope financial markets and Congress deter the worst."
Sunday, October 27, 2024
Washington state's cap-and-invest plan caused higher gas prices
See Gas Station Stunts and Tech Billionaires: The High-Stakes Battle Over Washington’s Climate Law: The move to repeal the state’s cap-and-invest plan is being watched by other states considering similar emissions reduction efforts by By H. Claire Brown of The WSJ. Excerpts:
"Washington gas prices hovering at around $3.91 a gallon"
"Under the law, the state auctions off greenhouse gas emissions allowances to polluting companies. The plan has generated more than $2 billion in revenue for the state, but the rollout also coincided with higher-than-expected increases in prices at the pump, leading to concerns about its impact on household wallets.
Estimates of the impact of the state law on gas prices vary, but some put it as high as 60 cents a gallon. Washington gas prices routinely exceed the U.S. average, which recently was $3.17 a gallon."
Washington’s cap-and-invest law applies to businesses that operate in the state and are responsible for the equivalent of at least 25,000 tons of carbon dioxide a year, such as fuel suppliers and utilities. It covers an estimated 75% of statewide emissions.
Each quarter, the state offers a set number of emissions allowances through an auction system. Companies bid for allowances, which give them the right to emit a certain amount of greenhouse gas. Over time, the state will auction off fewer allowances each quarter, and by 2050, the idea is that the program will reduce emissions by 95%.
Cap-and-invest programs are designed to ensure that businesses reduce carbon where it is most efficient, and the auction system helps set a market price for carbon. In 2023, the prices landed between $48.50 and $63.03. Companies that can slash emissions for less are motivated to do so, and others may opt to purchase allowances rather than adjust their operations. The allowances can be bought and sold on a secondary market.
The state has used the proceeds from the auctions on decarbonization initiatives like public transportation infrastructure.
Before the law rolled out, the state’s Department of Ecology estimated it might boost gas prices about 4 to 12 cents a gallon. Instead, they went up by 20 to 60 cents. Economic analyses attempting to quantify exactly how much of this increase was the result of the cap-and-invest law have varied widely, in part because the names of companies participating in the cap-and-invest program are confidential, so independent analyses are difficult to execute."
China’s One-Child Economic Disaster
Facing demographic decline of its own design, the Communist Party now may subsidize bigger families
"Chinese Finance Minister Lan Foan disappointed investors in a press conference last Saturday that offered few details about a fiscal stimulus for the sputtering economy. We’ll discuss the merits of such a plan when details emerge, but meanwhile a startling line caught our eye concerning the consequences of the country’s former one-child policy.
Mr. Foan said in particular the package “will respond to the changing situation of China’s population development” (according to a translation prepared by state media journalist Fred Gao). This is consistent with a Reuters report that Beijing is considering a monthly subsidy of around 800 yuan per child for a family’s second and third children.
What a stunning reversal. For decades Beijing enforced a one-child policy that was ghastly in the way only an authoritarian regime can achieve. The human cost was incalculable, particularly on Chinese parents subject to forced abortions or sterilizations. The social consequences have been catastrophic as sex-selective abortions skewed the population in favor of males and successive generations of Chinese have grown up without siblings, aunts or uncles.
Communist Party leaders will never admit to any of that, but even they recognize the policy has been an economic disaster. Intended to prevent the population from expanding beyond what a developing economy could support, the effect has been nearer the opposite. China’s aging and soon-to-be shrinking population is now an impediment to economic growth.
President Xi Jinping abandoned the one-child policy in 2016, and in 2021 the Party allowed parents to have up to three children. Apparently this isn’t having the desired effect, so now Beijing may attempt natalist subsidies. The problem for Beijing is that these subsidies haven’t worked anywhere they’ve been tried.
Prosperity has reduced child-bearing across the developed world, but democracies let nature and individual choice take their course. China’s Communist Party chose brutal coercion, with damaging consequences that are likely to persist for the foreseeable future. Chalk up another defeat for central planning—and for Western intellectuals who wished we could be more like China."
Biden’s Missing Electric-Vehicle Chargers
Union and equity rules bog down the $5 billion program
By Judge Glock. He is director of research at the Manhattan Institute.
"regulations and lavish handouts to favored groups have turned the EV charger program into another ineffective part of Mr. Biden’s equity and social-services agenda."
"Congress [in 2021] provided $5 billion over five years to fund a national network of EV charging ports. Almost three years later, the program has created 69 ports"
"The delays are due in part to regulations encouraging unionization, as well as the administration’s goal that at least 40% of clean-energy investments benefit “disadvantaged communities,” the areas that need EV chargers the least."
"To receive full subsidies, companies must abide by prevailing-wage and apprenticeship standards. But the IRS says companies can avoid penalties for violating these standards if they sign “project labor agreements,” which favor union workers and include “monitoring and administration by union officials.”"
"Last month the government proposed new accessibility standards for EV charging stations, requiring special communications features and lighter cables. The government estimates the regulation would cost almost $1 billion over the next seven years."
"This year, the Biden administration announced another $1.3 billion in grants for alternative fuel stations"
"Grant applicants are evaluated on whether they use project labor agreements, whether they use a “Climate and Economic Justice Screening Tool,” and whether they give priority to “minority-owned businesses” for contracts and “people of color” for hiring."
"newly installed federally funded chargers must be made domestically."
‘To Overthrow the World’ Review: Communists in Control
Long before the founding of the Soviet Union, communist thinkers became convinced that without violence they would never achieve power
By Nicholas Clairmont. He reviewed the book To Overthrow the World: The Rise and Fall and Rise of Communism by Sean McMeekin.
Mr. Clairmont is the Life and Arts editor of the Washington Examiner Magazine. Excerpts:
"In 1797, as the revolution in France cooled down following the Reign of Terror, François-Noël “Gracchus” Babeuf stood trial for organizing a putsch against the governing directorate running Paris at the time."
"what he had in fact done—recruit insurrectionists from the ranks of the police and military units to join his so-called Conspiracy of the Equals, with the intent to seize weapons and food stores, take control of Paris neighborhood by neighborhood, and execute France’s new rulers, along with any foreigners, royalists and other named enemies."
"he introduces us to some nonviolent utopian socialists. Robert Owen, for instance, sought to set up a planned community in 1820s Indiana that would have abolished all private possession, including marriage. It failed."
"“communists nowhere came to power through the ballot box.”"
"there were other, earlier revolutions, notably those across many parts of Europe in 1848 and in Russia in 1905, that, while not ending in successful communist takeovers, revealed to Europe’s communist thinkers that without violence they would never achieve power."
"“The real secret of Marxism-Leninism,” he tells us, “was not that Marx and Lenin had discovered an immutable law of history driven by ever-intensifying ‘class struggle,’ but that Lenin had shown how Communist revolutionaries could exploit the devastation of war” to seize and maintain power. Here the death count becomes eye-watering: Hundreds of thousands of kulaks—a name coined to scapegoat those peasants who had failed to turn over enough grain—are killed; a famine beginning in 1921, exacerbated by poor central planning, leaves so many dead that it is impossible to accurately calculate the toll to the nearest million. All this before Stalin takes over."
"nearly 23,000 Polish elites and military officers purged, their bodies deposited in a Russian forest; more than 34,000 Latvians killed or disappeared by the Soviet secret police."
"“Many famous Soviet ‘public works’ projects,” Mr. McMeekin points out, “were built by conscripted, unpaid workers—that is, slave laborers. Children worked, too, particularly on the collective farms, where the twelve-hour day was common for farmhands under fourteen"
"The story of communism is more accurately read as a history of violence than as a history of ideas."
Saturday, October 26, 2024
The Law Of Increasing Opportunity Cost And The Problem Of Big Government
Imagine a country that produces two kinds of goods, public goods and private goods.
Public goods are things like national defense. They benefit everyone and
it is hard to stop non-payers from getting it (it would be hard to stop
a non-payer from getting defended).
Private goods are those that only one person can enjoy and you can keep
non-payers from getting it. A Big Mac for example. If you don't pay, you
don't get it and if I eat a particular Big Mac, no one else can eat it.
What I am going to show is that as
government gets bigger, it will actually get more expensive in terms of
what we have to give up in the private sector. The bigger government
gets, the more costly it is.
Now also imagine that this country has 5 workers. Some are better at
making private goods (their skills are more entrepreneurial) and some
are better at making public goods (their skills are more bureaucratic).
The table below shows how much of each good each worker can make in a
day if they only produced that good.
These kinds of numbers make sense-we know in the real world people don't all have the same abilities. There is a best plumber, a best doctor, etc. The best doctor is not likely to be a good plumber and vice-versa.
The next table will show all the combinations of private goods and public goods that we can produce if we are at full-employment. That is, if we use all workers.
If we started with all workers making private goods, we make 25 (and 0 public goods). But if we want to make some public goods, we need to move a worker. The best move is to have worker V start making public goods. We give up only 3 private goods and we gain 7 public goods.
If we want more public goods, we would then move worker IV, then worker III and so on.
But each time we do this, we give up a different and increasing number of private goods for each public good gained. The next table shows this.
The more public goods we produce, the more costly they will be in terms of the private goods we have to give up. This is what makes the growing size of government so alarming. We can't see this so easily in the real world. Notice that the last public good costs 2.333 private goods, much more than the first one.
Here are some basic terms that economists use to discuss this issue:
Opportunity Cost-The value of the best foregone alternative. There is no such thing as a free lunch. If we want to build one more skyscraper, we may have to give up one submarine, since there may not be enough steel to go around (steel is scarce!).
The law of increasing opportunity cost-As more of a particular good is produced, the opportunity cost of its production rises. Why is the law of increasing opportunity cost true? Different resources are better suited to different productive activities. This is just about the same as saying people have different abilities, like some are more entrepreneurial and some are more bureaucratic.
Friday, October 25, 2024
1500 Hours: Haircuts, Pilots, and Regulatory Capture
"I don’t like to brag, but I got a decent haircut last week from a competent barber. Not bad eh? That very same week I was also landed safely in a $375 million jetliner by a competent pilot. From a basic common-sense standpoint, the two services could hardly be more different, but from a regulatory and licensing standpoint they are oddly, ridiculously similar.
The minimum number of pilot-in-command (PIC) hours required to gain a commercial pilot rating as an Airline Transport Pilot is 1,500 hours — this includes things like cross-country flight hours, night flying, instrument ratings, multi-engine time and so forth. This all seems sensible enough — most of us would hardly object if the people entrusted with our lives had some minimum qualifications.
Curiously enough, however, the other profession that requires 1,500 hours of rigorous training time is hairdresser. And no, I am not making this up.
The Institute for Justice has been highlighting the nation’s comically onerous license environment for years, pointing out that cosmetologists, for example, have to undergo approximately ten times the training time that Emergency Medical Technicians must undertake. They point out that, “given that there is no reason to believe EMTs are underregulated, this suggests these other occupations are overregulated.” Indeed.
But why? Who exactly stands to gain from such a patently hyper-regulated system? Is it government bureaucracy, bent on protecting fat licensing fees and the staffed departments that come with them? Possibly that’s some of it, but it seems to be more invidious than that. In this instance, it is the industry itself which provides the basic impetus for this kind of absurdity. According to an industry mouthpiece in Missouri (a perfectly middle-of-the-pack state in terms of licensing requirements), it is practitioners themselves who are the most motivated to maintain these extreme licensing requirements. Last year they crowed of their success at the state capitol:
“Legislators proposed House Bill 590, which would eliminate the license requirement for cosmetologists in Missouri. Professionals fought back, stating that cosmetology is a science and its practitioners need specialized training in the use of chemicals and sanitation. The public hearing on the bill was held in 2013 and no more hearings are scheduled at this time.”
Needless to say, the legislation did not pass, and Missouri’s licensing requirements remain rigidly enforced. Artificially erected barriers to entry, especially within relatively low-wage professions, are common. Their primary purpose is to keep out competitors from industries which are relatively broad and which require relatively low technical skill. Excessive licensing requirements are an attempt to put a veneer of difficulty on an otherwise easily-done profession in a rather naked effort to minimize competition. Preschool teachers, for example, are even more heavily licensed than hairdressers: a prospective candidate must undergo 2, 927 days (more than eight years) before they can purchase their license and be unleashed upon the state’s youngsters. If you care to be a gaming inspector (presumably checking slot machines), you don’t need many training hours but need to cough up the cool grand needed for a license. And so on. Excessive licensing requirements are everywhere and tend to cluster around the lowest-paid professions. It’s not a coincidence.
Schools and licensing programs, it turns out, are often the primary beneficiaries of this kind of market manipulation. “Z” Hair Academy, for instance, charges their students over $18,000 in tuition to earn certification through their training programs. Never fear, they assure prospective students, there are “scholarships” and Federal Financial Aid packages available. According to the Institute for Justice, the average student takes out $7,793 in federal student loans, and since most Missouri cosmetologists make less than $24,000 a year, it would require another three years of semi-indentured servitude just to pay back the tuition loans.
As if it weren’t bad enough, some of these academies open their services to the public, allowing their unlicensed students to practice their trade at discount rates. I got my perfectly good haircut from a trainee for $12 — about a third of the going rate. These academies therefore manage a double trick: two revenue streams under the convenient protection of government licensing requirements. All told, according to the Institute for Justice, Missouri’s licensing requirements cost the state’s economy $3.55 billion and lead to 38,500 fewer jobs each year by artificially stifling the supply of ready applicants to the field. It’s a racket.
While it’s tempting to place the blame on the coiffure-industrial complex, it’s important to remember that they can only operate this way by the effective manipulation of state control. It is a perfect case study for the phenomenon of regulatory capture: regulatory agencies created to protect the interests of consumers work instead to safeguard the commercial interests of the industries they are expected to be regulating.
Hairdressers are clearly not alone in this, and many a trade has circled its wagons against efforts to deregulate highly entrenched, disproportionally advantageous licensing schemes. In the end, however, these kinds of artificial barriers to the free market-directed flow of supplies and demands only tend to waste resources and diminish the public’s benefits. One thousand five hundred hours squandered in the repeated performance of a basic task like hair care doesn’t only waste the learner’s time, but also promotes a dependency mindset — a perception that the state is best positioned to authorize entrepreneurial activities.
The next time you step off a commercial airliner, take a look at the pilot’s hair — chances are, the hairdresser underwent more training. It’s a ridiculous waste and licensing requirements need to be thoroughly cleaned up."
SCOTUS Stumbles: EPA’s Power Plant Rule Is Inflicting Irreparable Harm
By Travis Fisher and Joshua Loucks of Cato.
"Last week, the Supreme Court issued an order that left many in disbelief. The Court denied several motions for stay (a legal pause) regarding the Environmental Protection Agency’s (EPA’s) Clean Power Plan (CPP) 2.0 rule after granting a stay of the original CPP in 2016 and elaborating on the Major Questions Doctrine in overturning the CPP on its merits in West Virginia v. EPA in 2022.
The EPA rule, which we call CPP 2.0 because it’s the second attempt at a CPP under section 111 of the Clean Air Act, hurts the reliability and affordability of electricity when both are already at risk. The EPA now requires existing coal and new natural gas power plants to significantly change their operations or shut them down entirely. CPP 2.0 is a costly and unlawful mandate for the unproven technology of carbon capture and sequestration/storage (CCS).
The fate of CPP 2.0 will be the same when the Supreme Court reviews it on the merits—it will be overturned because it plainly violates the statute it cites as authority from Congress. But it will hurt many more Americans than it needs to because the Supreme Court took a narrow view of “irreparable harm.”
The irreparable harm ignored by the Supreme Court is that demand for electricity in the United States is growing again in exceptional ways (in part due to unforeseen growth in computing load), and CPP 2.0 is preventing economic growth—and possibly causing electricity shortages—by mandating impossible standards for existing and new electricity supplies.
The CPP 2.0 Mandate
In its most basic form, CPP 2.0 requires existing coal and new natural gas power plants to implement CCS on an unprecedented scale. For existing coal-fired power plants, CPP 2.0 requires the owners of any plant that might remain operational after 2039 to capture and store 90 percent of its carbon dioxide emissions by 2032. (Some less stringent options are available for coal plants that will be closed by 2032 or 2040.)
Likewise, the rule requires any new combined-cycle natural gas–fired power plants operating above “baseload” levels (at an annual capacity factor above 40 percent) to reduce their carbon emissions by 90 percent by 2032 by implementing CCS.
How did the EPA come up with this rule? Dating back to the 1970 Clean Air Act amendments, Congress authorized the EPA to issue nationally binding emissions standards for stationary sources like power plants through section 111 using proven technology as a baseline.
Specifically, EPA’s standards of performance under section 111 must be based on “the best system of emission reduction which (taking into account the cost of achieving such reduction and any nonair quality health and environmental impact and energy requirements) the Administrator determines has been adequately demonstrated.” (emphasis added)
In CPP 2.0, the EPA claimed CCS at a 90 percent capture rate had been adequately demonstrated, which is a patently false account of the facts on the ground. This is the key issue of statutory interpretation relevant to CPP 2.0, and we believe the rule will fail on EPA’s fundamental misreading of the statute and/or its misreading of the facts in the record.
The short version of the merits argument is this: CCS depends on a mind-bogglingly large set of new infrastructure (rivaling the existing network of fossil fuel infrastructure itself), including CO2 pipelines to carry enormous amounts of CO2 from power plants to injection sites. Such infrastructure may be impossible to build and certainly has not been “adequately demonstrated.” For more detailed legal and technical arguments, see comments on the proposed rule.
The only power plant in the United States that captures anywhere near 90 percent of CO2 emissions is perhaps the Petra Nova plant in Texas, which has not operated continuously and does not technically sequester CO2 at all—it injects CO2 into oil wells in a process known as enhanced oil recovery. Another power plant often cited by proponents of CCS (and explicitly cited by the EPA) is the Boundary Dam project in Canada, which has consistently underperformed on its CCS goal of—you guessed it—90 percent.
Thus, EPA’s emissions standard is far too stringent because it is based on plants that are located near profitable CO2 injection and storage sites or are falling woefully short of the EPA’s goal. A rule mandating 90 percent CCS nationwide is therefore at odds with the part of the statute that says the “best system of emission reduction” must be “adequately demonstrated.”
CPP 2.0’s Irreparable Harm
The mandate to close existing coal plants and prevent the building of new “baseload” natural gas plants is a recipe for electricity shortages, skyrocketing electricity prices, or a mix of both. The lack of certainty regarding which set of rules a power plant owner is likely to face in the coming years is itself a deterrent to building or retaining needed supplies.
In practice, the much-needed new electricity supplies are likely to come from less efficient simple-cycle natural gas power plants—essentially methane-fueled jet engines—which will increase costs and preclude more efficient investments until CPP 2.0 is finally overturned.
At the wholesale level, prices will be set more often by these less efficient units with higher marginal costs, meaning wholesale electricity prices will be higher than necessary. Further, the US Energy Information Administration (EIA) estimates only 2.6 gigawatts of new natural gas–fired power plants will come online in 2024, while 3.8 GW will be retired.
Coal plant closures will also reduce power supplies. PJM Interconnection Inc., the largest electricity market in North America by revenue and volume, has issued stark warnings about the collision course we are on between growing demand and falling supply, stating that there is a “timing mismatch between resource retirements, load growth and the pace of new generation entry.” CPP 2.0 exacerbates such a mismatch because it would force the retirement of coal units, which produced 16 percent of the electricity in the United States last year.
To be clear, we don’t expect anyone at the EPA, the Supreme Court, or any government agency to accurately predict the timing and scale of Americans’ future electricity needs. Efforts to centrally plan electricity markets are likely to lead to supply shortages, increased costs, top-down rationing, and rolling blackouts. But that is precisely why CPP 2.0 is so harmful—it allows the EPA to be the national gatekeeper for new electricity supplies, which will have disastrous consequences.
The Court’s Mistake
In his statement about the denial of applications for stay, Justice Brett Kavanaugh argued that applicants “are unlikely to suffer irreparable harm before the Court of Appeals for the DC Circuit decides the merits” because “applicants need not start compliance work until June 2025.” Unfortunately, that is untrue. For would-be builders of new natural gas power plants, the irreparable harm likely began in May 2023 (the date of the proposed rule) and was cemented in the final version of CPP 2.0, which featured an effective date of July 8, 2024.
While Justice Kavanaugh’s approach may make sense in the legal compliance world, it ignores economic decisions that predate compliance. As Frederic Bastiat might say, the court focused on what is seen—the compliance measures undertaken by plants that are already built—and failed to recognize the unseen harms. We cannot see, for example, the business activities or consumer savings that might have occurred if the Supreme Court had granted the motions for stay. In other words, CPP 2.0 is already causing irreparable harm because it’s preventing much-needed electricity supplies that would be built in its absence. (We note that Justice Clarence Thomas would have granted the applications for stay, and Justice Samuel Alito did not participate.)
PJM and other grid operators articulated this harm in their amicus brief, stating that the EPA has “failed to adequately consider the impact of premature retirements driven by the Rule’s compliance timelines.” They also highlighted how investments in the grid, particularly large power plants, are based on “the expected revenues associated with continuing operation of the unit. Unit owners may decide to retire units early rather than incur additional expense and risk.” Premature power plant closures—and the stalling of new supplies in an era of demand growth—are the irreparable harm the Court failed to see.
Conclusion
Supreme Court justices clearly understand the law. However, the order in this case demonstrated that many of them do not understand market processes and fall into the knowledge problem trap of attempting to assume the unknowable. By denying the motions to stay CPP 2.0, the Supreme Court squandered a perfect opportunity to limit executive branch overreach in the new post-Chevron era and protect millions of Americans from government-induced harm."